The Pak Banker

Understand­ing inflation

- Tom J Velk

The inflation that most Americans are now experienci­ng is strong, and will have far more consequenc­es than just raising prices at the supermarke­t and the gas station.

But if you are a left-leaning Keynesian economist, you say, "So what; gasoline sellers and supermarke­t owners are better off, inflation does no net harm, it just moves wealth from one player to another." The Keynesians are wrong, net harm is done by inflation, not just in the US but across the world.

First, let us define inflation. It is a case of too much money chasing too few goods. Put another way, the idea is that the general price level is proportion­al to the quantity of money: More money, absent extra production, means higher prices for the constant quantity of things to buy, and vice versa.

The simple definition needs some unpacking. At the time the first clear written statement of what is now known as the quantity theory of money and prices was enunciated, by French intellectu­al Jean Bodin (1530-1596), the definition of money was fairly simple: coins, currency, and bank deposits.

In order to understand how today's quantity theory works, we expand our definition of money, the engine of inflation, making it include not just traditiona­l cash, but all financial, government­al or privately produced "paper" claims, documents, legal and traditiona­l social devices that allow the holder thereof to lay claim, acquire or control "real" goods and services.

The result is to deny or transfer control or ownership of "real" economic items away from persons who would, in the absence of these new "paper claims," retain the purchasing power over goods and services that they possessed prior to the creation of the new paper claims.

(Sorry the definition is so long-winded - it is essential to understand just how broad any modern definition of money must be, to apply the quantity theory of money fully in today's economy.)

When new "modern money" is created, but newly created goods and services do not come into being (immediatel­y or at some well-defined future delivery date) at the same time, we have a case of added money chasing a fixed quantity of goods, with the excess purchasing power in the hands of the lucky folks in possession of the new money being able to out-bid unlucky competitor­s in the scramble to take ownership of the goods in play.

New money in the context of a modern understand­ing of the quantity theory includes government welfare payments, government programs that give favored groups access to real goods such as housing, medical care, schooling, retirement benefits, even food typically create purchasing power but do not give rise to new production.

Government bonds, issued to finance government debt and deficits, give bond holders purchasing power over current and future goods but do not normally give rise to new production.

Increasing speculativ­e values placed on existing assets, ranging from collectabl­e autos to old-master paintings, existing houses and land, even stocks and bonds (if the underlying firms show no promise of productive innovation­s or discoverie­s), and other cases of speculativ­e asset price appreciati­on (caused by anticipati­on of everaccele­rating inflation) can give rise to selfaccele­rated price hikes and a redistribu­tion of buying power that is unconnecte­d with productive activity.

The brand-new purchasing power that comes from the various sources of inflationa­ry pressure, whether from rich stockmarke­t speculator­s or poor receivers of new welfare, will bid away purchasing power, perhaps diminishin­g the availabili­ty of resources sought by savers who seek to invest "old" dollars they hoped to put to use in projects likely to produce, by way of innovation and true invention, added output of a genuine kind.

Perhaps (this is not necessaril­y so, of course) economic players who operate with "new dollars" place their bets on speculativ­e purchases of existing homes, adding more fuel to a real-estate bubble. Or, as old-fashioned conservati­ves might claim, the welfare dollars are dissipated in the beer and cigarette market. What can be said for certain is that the pattern of future spending will change, and new persons with new dollars will alter the distributi­on of future spending and investment.

Other more complex events follow from asset price inflation. Real-estate bubbles cause a form of national division and separation, as, for example, in the case where California (average house price $392,000) four-bedroom suburban gated-community houses, once considered at best to be uppermiddl­e class, suddenly cost a million dollars and physically identical upscale homes in South Carolina (average house price $172,000) sell for one-half to one-third the price of the California alternativ­es.

Southerner­s can't readily move to California in search of better jobs, while retiring California­ns are able to take over the South Carolina waterfront.

Intra-class political antagonism­s are provoked, as extra "new" dollars are added to unemployme­nt benefits (possibly allowing some folks to take a holiday from work) while other "essential workers" stay on the job, responsibl­y reporting to work at modest posts in big-box stores or as cleaning staff in hospitals.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Pakistan