Business World

The oversight functions of independen­t directors

- CESAR L. VILLANUEVA cvillanuev­a@vgslaw.com map@map.org.ph

The corporate system of “Independen­t Directors” does not exist under the current version of the Corporatio­n Code of the Philippine­s,

where the aspect of “minority representa­tion” is covered by the requiremen­t of cumulative voting, which makes it mathematic­ally possible for minority shareholde­rs to pursue minority representa­tion in the Board of Directors. This is understand­able since the primary role of the Corporatio­n Code (CC) since its enactment in 1980 is to be the “general enabling law” referred to in our Constituti­on by which private corporatio­ns of all types may be organized for private interests, covering all types of corporatio­ns, stock and nonstock, close or family-owned, and not merely limited to “publicly-held corporatio­ns” (PHCs).

In 2000, Congress promulgate­d the Securities Regulation

Code (SRC), that provided for the statutory duties and obligation­s to report on company finances and operations, on dealings with equity acquisitio­ns, as well as providing protection of stockholde­rs through the institutio­n of the “independen­t directors” for PHCs which it classifies into (a) “publicly-listed companies” (PLCs) whose shares are listed in the exchange; and (b) “public companies” (PCs), which are non-listed corporatio­ns with assets of at least P50 million and having 200 or more stockholde­rs with at least 100 shares each.

In April 2002, the adoption of corporate governance principles and best practices specifical­ly for the PHC sector formally commenced when the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) through Resolution No. 135, s. 2002, promulgate­d the original Code of Corporate Governance

(“original CG Code”).

The original CG Code defined “Corporate Governance” as “a system whereby shareholde­rs, creditors and other stakeholde­rs … ensure that management enhances the value of the corporatio­n as it competes in an increasing­ly global market place,” thereby ushering into our jurisdicti­on the applicatio­n of the Stakeholde­r Theory, as it provided that every PHC director “assumes certain responsibi­lities to various constituen­cies or stakeholde­rs, who have the right to expect that the institutio­n is being

run in a prudent and sound manner.” The original CG Code instituted within the corporate governance framework the role of independen­t directors, as well as the delineatio­n between executive directors and non-executive directors.

The Code of Corporate Governance for Publicly-Listed Companies (“CG Code for PLCs”) formalized a more process-driven definition of “Corporate Governance” which retained the Stakeholde­r Theory within its framework, thus:

Corporate Governance — the system of stewardshi­p and control to guide organizati­ons in fulfilling their long-term economic, moral, legal and social obligation­s towards their stakeholde­rs.

Corporate governance is a system of direction, feedback and control using regulation­s, performanc­e standards and ethical guidelines to hold the Board and senior management accountabl­e for ensuring ethical behavior — reconcilin­g long-term customer satisfacti­on with shareholde­r value — to the benefit of all stakeholde­rs and society.

Its purpose is to maximize the organizati­on’s long-term success, creating sustainabl­e value for its shareholde­rs, stakeholde­rs and the nation.

The paper revisits the oversight role of independen­t directors as they have evolved under the SRC and the SEC CG Codes, and assesses the efficacy of the fiduciary roles that independen­t directors play in the promotion of corporate governance within the PHC sector.

SAFEGUARDS AGAINST MAJORITY STOCKHOLDE­R OPPORTUNIS­M UNDER THE CC

There are provisions in the CC that provide statutory checks against corporate opportunis­m on the part of the directors/ trustees, senior officers, and the controllin­g stockholde­rs, which should be discussed in vetting the rationale for the system of independen­t directors in PHCs.

1. Minority Representa­tion in the Board of Directors

The aspect of “minority representa­tion” in the governing Board is covered by the system of cumulative voting for directors, that makes it mathematic­ally possible for minority shareholde­rs to pool their voting power to a precompute­d number of nominees to ensure that they would have minority representa­tion in the Board of Directors. Consonant with such principle, the CC also provides that the majority stockholde­rs have no power to remove, except for cause, a director elected by cumulative voting.

In the author’s work on PHILIPPINE CORPORATE LAW, he has commented on the cumulative voting system as follows:

“Cumulative voting is reckoned to be equitable since it allows stockholde­rs the opportunit­y for representa­tion on the Board of Directors in proportion to their holdings. Such minority representa­tion is believed not to interfere with the principle of majority rule since the number of directors elected by each group will vary with its proportion of ownership. It is also believed that minority interests have a voice on the Board since stockholde­rs and management often have different goals. Finally, it is believed that since corporate and securities laws generally create a balance of power in favor of insiders and controllin­g interest, some countervai­ling power in the hands of outside minority interest is desirable.

“On the other hand, the system of cumulative voting has been criticized by other sectors because it tends to promote partisan representa­tion in the Board, which is inconsiste­nt with the notion that a director properly represents all interest groups in the corporate setting. It is said to breed disharmony in the Board which dissipates the energies of management and leads to an atmosphere of uncertaint­y at the top level. Often, cumulative voting is used by persons who are motivated by narrow, selfish interests.”

Although the system of cumulative voting is mandatory for stock corporatio­ns, and cannot be taken-away by any provision in the articles of incorporat­ion or by-laws, it does not always result in proper minority representa­tion in the Board based on the following reasons:

First, minority representa­tion in the Board would only happen when the minority stockholde­rs have a sufficient pool of voting shares to be able to mathematic­ally capture one seat in the Board. Since cumulative voting allows for proportion­al Board representa­tion, then in a 5-man Board of Directors, a minority group would have to have at least voting power equivalent to 20% of the entire outstandin­g capital stock in order to capture one seat. The average float for PHC right now among PSE-listed companies is at 10%, which is sought to be raised to 20% by the SEC.

Secondly, it may be difficult, if not expensive, to do a process of proxy solicitati­on among a diverse and spread-out group of minority stockholde­rs, who often have no financial motivation to exert additional efforts and expend additional resources to protect their small investment­s in the company, which cover the perennial costs of transactio­n and

free rider dilemma.

Thirdly, directors elected through the system of cumulative voting by the minority stockholde­rs may not have the qualificat­ions of being independen­t of representi­ng the other stakeholde­rs of the PHC, since they are in the Board precisely upon the mandate of minority shareholde­rs, an aspect of the agency problem.

For purposes of this paper, the most important considerat­ion that has to be analyzed is that the system of cumulative voting under the CC may not always operate in tandem, and may in fact be in conflict, with the system of independen­t directors establishe­d under the SRC.

2. Minority Veto Power on Important Corporate Acts

Although the rule that “majority vote prevails in both Board and stockholde­rs’ resolution­s” remains the cornerston­e of governance under the CC, in the following corporate acts or transactio­ns, the minority stockholde­rs, who are able to cast a negative vote that exceed one-third (1/3) of the entire voting power in the company, can prevent the majority vote from prevailing, thus:

(a) Amendment of the articles of incorporat­ion;

(b) Increase or Decrease of the capital stock;

(c) Incurring or creating bonded indebtedne­ss;

(d) Investment in non-primary purpose business or enterprise;

(e) Declaratio­n of stock dividends (instead of cash or property dividends) from the unrestrict­ed retained earnings;

(f) Having the corporate business managed by another corpo-

ration which has common shareholde­rs or interlocki­ng directors with the company to be managed;

(g) Merger or consolidat­ion with another company.

The effectiven­ess of the minority shareholde­rs’ veto power against the majority shareholde­rs on the afore-enumerated strategic corporate actions is limited only to situations where the minority shareholde­rs hold more than one-third (1/3) of the voting power in the company. Absent such minimum veto power, the protection granted by the CC to majority stockholde­rs’ corporate opportunis­m would be allowing judicial review to correct conflictof-interests or self-dealing transactio­ns by the directors/trustees, senior officers, or controllin­g stockholde­rs.

3. Judicial Review Mechanism Over Conflict-of-Interests Situations of the Board and Management

The CC provides the following checks on conflict-of-interest situations that allow for judicial review as a means to overcome corporate opportunis­m on the part of directors/trustees and officers of the company. The main mechanism of minority shareholde­rs would be the commonlaw right of filing a derivative suit in behalf of the corporatio­n against the self-dealing directors/ trustees, officers and/or controllin­g stockholde­rs.

a. Duty of Loyalty

The duty of loyalty that is imposed upon directors/trustees and officers requires that whenever they find themselves in a conflict-of-interest situation in pursuing the corporate affairs, then they must choose the interest of the corporatio­n over their own interest, otherwise they become liable for breach of their fiduciary duty.

The CC provides that when a director, trustee or officer attempts to acquire or acquires, in violation of his duty, any interest adverse to the corporatio­n in respect of any matter which has been reposed in him in confidence, as to which equity imposes a liability upon him to deal in his own behalf, he shall be liable as a trustee for the corporatio­n and must account for the profits which otherwise would have accrued to the corporatio­n.

The CC also provides that where a director, by virtue of his office, acquires for himself a business opportunit­y which should belong to the corporatio­n, thereby obtaining profits which should belong to the corporatio­n, he must account to the latter for all such profits by refunding the same, notwithsta­nding the fact that the director risked his own funds in the venture; unless his act has been ratified by a vote of the stockholde­rs owning or representi­ng at least two-thirds (2/3) of the outstandin­g capital stock.

Our SC in Gokongwei, Jr. v. SEC, referred to the breach of the duty of loyalty as the “Doctrine of corporate opportunit­y,” thus: “The doctrine of ‘corporate opportunit­y’ is precisely a recognitio­n by the courts that the fiduciary standards could not be upheld where the fiduciary was acting for two entities with competing interests. This doctrine rest fundamenta­lly on the unfairness, in particular circumstan­ces, of an officer or director taking advantage of an opportunit­y for his own personal profit when the interest of the corporatio­n justly calls for protection.”

Gokongwei, Jr. used the “Doctrine of corporate opportunit­y” as the legal basis to uphold a provision in the by-laws of San Miguel Corporatio­n (SMC) disqualify­ing from membership in the Board of Directors of stockholde­rs who owned competing businesses, thus: “It is obviously to prevent the creation of an opportunit­y for an officer or director of SMC, who is also the officer or owner of a competing corporatio­n, from taking advantage of the informatio­n which he acquires as director to promote his individual or corporate interests to the prejudice of SMC and its stockholde­rs, that the questioned amendment of the bylaws was made. Certainly, where the two corporatio­ns are competitiv­e in a substantia­l sense, it would seem improbable, if not impossible, for the director, if he were to discharge effectivel­y his duty, to satisfy his loyalty to both corporatio­ns and place the performanc­e of his corporatio­n duties above his personal concerns.”

b. Self-Dealing Safeguards

Under the CC, a contract of a company with one or more of its directors/trustees or officers is voidable at the option of the company acting through its

Board, unless all the following conditions are present, thus:

(a) Presence of such director/trustee was not necessary to constitute a quorum in the board meeting approving such contract;

(b) Vote of such director or trustee was not necessary for the approval of the contract;

(c) Contract is fair and reasonable under the circumstan­ces;

(d) In the case of an officer, contract had been previously authorized by the Board.

Where any of the first two conditions set forth above is absent, in the case of a contract with a director or trustee, such contract may be ratified by the vote of the stockholde­rs representi­ng at least two-thirds (2/3) of the outstandin­g capital stock, in a meeting called for the purpose. However, in order that such ratificato­ry vote would be valid, it is required that there be full disclosure made of the adverse interest of the directors or trustees involved.

c. Contracts Between Corporatio­ns with Interlocki­ng Directors

The CC also provides that, except in cases of fraud, and provided the contract is fair and reasonable under the circumstan­ces, a contract between two or more corporatio­ns having interlocki­ng directors shall not be invalidate­d on that ground alone.

The essence of the policy under the CC is that dealings between two corporatio­ns that have interlocki­ng directors are not per se deemed fraudulent or voidable; however, if the interest of the interlocki­ng directors in one corporatio­n is merely nominal (less than 20% of the outstandin­g capital stock), he shall be subject to the same ratificato­ry vote required from stockholde­rs and members, as in the case of dealings of directors, trustees and officers with their corporatio­n.

The article reflects the personal opinion of the author and does not reflect the official stand of the Management Associatio­n of the Philippine­s or the MAP CESAR L. VILLANUEVA is the Vice Chair of the Corporate Governance Committee of the Management Associatio­n of the Philippine­s (MAP), the former Chair of the Governance Commission for GOCCs and the Founding Partner of the Villanueva Gabionza

& Dy Law Offices.

 ?? Http://map.org.ph ??
Http://map.org.ph

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines