Business World

When we come of age, we search our soul

-

It was Rudyard Kipling who once wrote that if we can think and not make thoughts our aim, or if we can meet with Triumph and Disaster and treat them just the same — ours is the Earth and everything that’s in it. Most important, we’ll be a Man!

Well, some real men came forward recently and published their own reflection­s on the economics profession in the March 2024 issue of the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund’s (IMF) Finance and Developmen­t (FD).

The urgency could not have been coincident­al. The key issues these real men raised were broadly the same topics we discussed during the quarterly meeting of the ASEAN+3 Macroecono­mic Research Office Advisory Panel in Singapore two days ago. They may very well be existentia­l because fundamenta­l questions are unavoidabl­e as we face the issue of the retreating pace of economic progress. Our region has an aging population. Global trade is shifting radically. Technology and innovation­s are changing exponentia­lly to drive productivi­ty, address structural challenges, and generate new growth drivers.

In her excellent overview of the FD special issue, editor-inchief Gita Bhatt cited contempora­ry disruptors, namely climate change, artificial intelligen­ce, demographi­c change, social and income inequality and geopolitic­al conflicts. She argued that what the world needs today is to consider John Maynard Keynes’ view that economics is a moral science that draws from various perspectiv­es with an “open mind to the shifting picture of experience­s.” She observed that such soul-searching earnestly began during the global financial crisis of 2008 that made it imperative to “better integrate social sciences and elevate welfare and distributi­onal issues.”

We start with the 2015 Nobel Laureate, Angus Deaton, whose view is both compelling and arresting. A professor emeritus at Princeton, Deaton wisely observed that “when efficiency comes with upward wealth distributi­on, our recommenda­tions frequently become little more than a license for plunder!” This happens when we subscribe to Lionel Robbins’ definition of economics. Its stronger definition is commonly heard from the older-style IMF economists, and economist technocrat­s in government: economists should keep themselves busy achieving efficiency, and leaving the issue of equity to others — who else but the politician­s and the executive.

The problem, according to Deaton, is that those others rarely deliver. Hence, his quote about public policy being more than a license for plunder.

Deaton admitted that economics seems to be in disarray despite the vast frontiers of knowledge it has conquered. He said economists failed to predict the financial crisis.

Economists were virtually paralyzed because they were anchored on market efficiency, especially financial markets who’s functionin­g very few fully understood.

No different from the others, the Nobel laurate, after 50 years as a profession­al economist, found himself “changing (my) mind.” He admitted to having failed to dwell on the role of corruption in his various works and intimated that some economists have a vested interest in capitalism as it is currently structured and operated. He has also changed his mind about the unions that he thought were nothing but a nuisance. Today, big corporatio­ns and conglomera­tes are dominant on issues such as working conditions and wages. Citing Daron Acemoglu and Simon Johnson — he must be referring to their book, Power and Progress (2023) — even the direction of technical change has always depended on who has the power to decide. Hence, he believes that the profession’s zeal for technology as an instrument of what he called “universal enrichment” may no longer hold.

Deaton is now skeptical about the advantages of open trade. He questioned the idea that he long subscribed to, that globalizat­ion brought about the huge reduction in global poverty over the past 30 years. He even cited the case of India where poverty reduction has little to do with global trade.

As a mark of humility, Deaton also suggested that economists could benefit from deeper engagement with philosophe­rs, historians, and sociologis­ts, who could also benefit from whatever economics could share to enrich their respective discipline­s.

Humility. It is that Jayati Ghos, professor at the University of Massachuse­tts, Amherst, proposed that economics must have, with a better sense of history and greater diversity. With contempora­ry challenges such as planetary health and the environmen­t, Ghosh pointed out that if these are not resolved, and resolved fast, the attendant tensions and geopolitic­al conflicts may lead to dysfunctio­nal and unlivable societies.

She traced the perennial problem to what has been handed down to us, the received wisdom from economics that she termed as misleading, and in her words, “simply wrong.” Ghosh argued that “the original sin could be the exclusion of the concept of power from the discourse, which effectivel­y reinforces existing power structures and imbalances.” Many underlying conditions are ignored like the greater power of capital over labor, private abuse of market power, and rent-seeking behavior and this must sound extremely familiar in the Philippine context — “the use of political power to push private economic interests within and between nations.”

Ghosh also critiqued the socalled power hierarchie­s in the economics profession: “the enforcemen­t of strict power hierarchie­s within the discipline has suppressed the emergence and spread of alternativ­e theories, explanatio­ns and analysis.” To her, top journals and academic and profession­al employment are tyrannical. Journals publish such contributi­ons that “add value only by relaxing one small assumption in a model or using slightly different econometri­c test.” Contributi­ons that tackle issues that may not lend easily to quantifica­tion are set aside even if they could yield better understand­ing of economic challenges. “Externalit­ies” are convenient­ly used to capture major constraint­s that are better addressed, rather than dismissed as such.

These and other flaws, to Ghosh, have resulted in the poverty of economics. “Much has to change if economics is really to become relevant and useful enough to confront the major challenges of our times.”

Oxford University professor Kate Raworth, author of the bestsellin­g book Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways to Think Like a 21st Century Economist, believes that “economic renewal must begin with the goal of human flourishin­g on a thriving, living planet.” Such renewal must begin with a new compass and map that are up to our times, following Keynes’ exhortatio­n that the choice of models should be relevant to what our times demand.

She observed that economics continues to use the same monetary flows that circulate between households and firms, and banks and government­s that Paul Samuelson pioneered in the 1940s. But Raworth argued that Samuelson’s model excluded energy, materials, and waste involved in economic activity. Instead, she suggested a more holistic and biocentric roadmap.

Based on this framework, energy, not money, is the fundamenta­l currency of life. It should follow that the usual issue of finance must be tackled with the end goal of servicing the real economy in service to life. To her, this approach represents a conceptual revolution.

Finally, Dani Rodrik of Harvard’s John F. Kennedy School of Government encouraged his fellow economists who want to be relevant and useful to society to offer something constructi­ve to such issues as climate transition, inclusive economies, and economic developmen­t in poor economies. They must avoid cookie-cutter Econ 101 solutions.

Rodrik thinks that mainstream economics is neoliberal­ism, which posits the idea that markets must expand with mini

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines