The Manila Times

A non-economist’s

-

land the value of its ecological services.

Even if it serves as a refuge for wildlife, or as a critical watershed that protects the water supply of a community, financial analysis would always see land in terms of its market price per hectare which will be a cost if purchased to build a golf course. Socio- economic analysis will however compute the economic value of wildlife, or the protective services provided to the community’s water supply, as a cost if the land is converted to a golf course because it is the value that will be lost to the economy.

In short, the applicatio­n of socio- economic benefit- cost analysis rests on what resource economists would label as a with or without framework, where economic costs and benefits are computed by comparing the supply of real resources in the economy without the project, and with the project. An increase in the supply, or when the current use of the resource has a lower contributi­on to the economy compared to the proposed, would be valued as a benefit. A decrease in the supply, or when the current use has a higher contributi­on to the economy compared to the proposed, would be valued as a cost.

calculated as the depletion in the cash resources of an economy, such as in terms of government

such as increased productivi­ty and income. Financial analysis does not apply the with or without framework, but tacitly operates on computing the

and outputs associated with the implementa­tion of a proposed project or interventi­on without considerin­g opportunit­y costs.

A shift to federalism is an interventi­on that would have serious implicatio­ns on the economy. Unfortunat­ely, what most economists are doing is not socio- economic analysis but only financial analysis. And here, it appears that they just focus on the cost side of the equation without factoring in the benefits that would necessaril­y follow. They anticipate only the increases in expenditur­es in terms of actual costs of the creation of items in the government bureaucrac­y, and the supposed impacts of these on prices of commoditie­s by implying that federalism will drive inflation and interest rates to skyrocket. There is also a tendency to look at the implementa­tion of federalism as an addition of a new layer of governance, without looking at the attendant re- deployment of assets and resources. This is a natural pitfall when one looks at market prices of anticipate­d expenses using a before and after analytical framework, instead of economic values that probe opportunit­y costs in relation to the redeployme­nt of assets and resources.

President Duterte’s economic managers paint a bleak scenario for the economy if we adopt federalism. They point to the enormous amounts of financial resources that would be needed for the shift. However, what they fail to point out is that these are not additional resources that government should budget on top of the existing government expenditur­es, but are simply resources that would be redeployed.

An applicatio­n of socio- economic benefit- cost analysis would reveal that a shift to federalism will not lead to a massive additional burden to government equivalent to the establishm­ent of new items and offices. Rather, since the local government units will now be under the exclusive powers of regional states, and that many functions of national government agencies will be transferre­d to regional states, there will be no reduction in the supply of real resources in the economy since what will occur is simply a transfer of existing expenses from the national to the regional levels. That is, the value of the expenses that the regions will incur in paying for the salaries of transferre­d personnel and administra­tive overhead of regional offices of national government agencies ( a cost) coincides with the current expenses for the same in a unitary set- up which will now be saved when these personnel and offices are transferre­d to the regions ( which is technicall­y a negative cost or a benefit).

What is however not factored in by the economic managers are the benefits that will accrue brought about by the redeployme­nt, in terms of lower coordinati­ng expenses between national and regional offices, and the concrete impacts these will have in reducing the transactio­n costs for processing and approval of projects, documents and decisions which will be enabled by federalism. These benefits are never considered in financial analysis, but are in fact considered as benefits in socio- economic analysis. They become negative opportunit­y costs, in the sense that the cost of transactin­g with a centrally located agency in Imperial Manila in a unitary set- up is definitely higher than if the transactio­ns are done locally in the regions. The cost of travel and communicat­ion to maintain a link between the regional offices and the central office would be reduced, if not foregone. These items are easily computed for their market prices which even a financial analysis can cover.

But what financial analysis cannot factor into the equation would be the socio- economic value of the sense of autonomy that the regions would enjoy. After all, the political empowermen­t of regions is not a marketable good that can be readily calculated by economic managers who are focused only on financial burdens to the economy if we shift to federalism, but one that would yield priceless non- marketable benefits to the local political economies in the regions.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines