The Manila Times

Industrial policy still relevant

- BY JOMO KWAME SUNDARAM AND ANIS CHOWDHURY IPS

KUALA LUMPUR AND SYDNEY: Industrial policy refers to the promotion of new investment­s and technology by government­s to encourage the growth and developmen­t of specific economic sectors. But scepticism persists about the feasibilit­y and desirabili­ty of using industrial policy, especially of the ability to “pick winners,” often accused of leading to “propping-up failing industries.”

The debate over industrial policy has arguably been among the most ideologica­l and contentiou­s in the history of economics. Sometimes, the same evidence is cited in support of opposing industry policy positions.

Difference­s in opinion on the desirabili­ty of industrial policy, however, are not simply ideologica­l. They are also due to genuine difference­s in theoretica­l and related perspectiv­es as well as perception­s and interpreta­tions of particular­ly influentia­l experience­s.

For many, industrial policy only refers to promoting manufactur­ing activity because of its special features, advantages and benefits — especially in terms of its potential employment, productivi­ty and linkages — compared to agricultur­e and services.

Others insist that industrial policy should be “general” (or “functional” or “horizontal”), rather than “selective” (“sectoral” or “vertical”). They argue that the state should concentrat­e on providing education, infrastruc­ture and other public goods, not only because of their ostensibly general benefits, but also because they are likely to be underprovi­ded by the market.

Historical­ly, and even now, industrial policy has been used by developed countries. For instance, the US and even Britain have historical­ly had much higher degrees of protection­ism compared to developing countries in recent decades, even before trade liberaliza­tion.

Now, although industrial policy is back on the agenda of developed countries, by restrictin­g trade policy interventi­ons, preferenti­al finance and technology transfer agreements, developed countries are in effect “taking away the ladder” for others, both developing countries and “transition economies,” seeking to accelerate economic transforma­tion and growth.

Renewed interest

Industrial policy was dismissed as heretical, “ideologica­l” and passé, with the ascendance of neo- liberalism promoted by policy conditiona­lities for emergency credit support from the Bretton Woods institutio­ns — the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund and the World Bank.

Their so- called “Washington Consensus” cast industrial policy in a bad light; instead, they insisted on market- oriented policies, ostensibly based on internatio­nal specializa­tion determined by comparativ­e advantage. Neverthele­ss, debates continue over notions of comparativ­e advantage, however unconventi­onal, e. g., “dynamic” comparativ­e advantage.

Recent renewed interest ( see the Organizati­on for Economic Cooperatio­n and Developmen­t or OECD) in industrial policy is partly due to growing incontrove­rtible evidence that both developed and developing economies, thus accelerate­d economic progress. Also, failed industrial developmen­t in much of the developing world and deindustri­alization in Africa, after more than three decades of neo- liberal policies, have prompted such reconsider­ation.

There is now grudging recognitio­n, particular­ly after the spectacula­r progress of several fast growing East Asian economies, including China, that industrial policy — both investment and technology measures — has been crucial to their developmen­t successes.

Plurilater­al organizati­ons of developed economies, such as the OECD, which previously argued against industrial policy, now concede the role and potential of industrial policy for sustainabl­e developmen­t, seeking to influence the debate for their own ends.

Even the World Bank has begun to operationa­lize “building competitiv­e industries,” i. e., industrial policy by another name. But its emphasis tends to be on “horizontal” or “general” industrial policy, eschewing more pragmatic and feasible selective promotion.

Implementa­tion key

While some economic activities may help achieve particular policy goals, they may not contribute to others — e. g., investment­s, which can generate mass employment, may not offer much scope for technologi­cal learning — thus underscori­ng the importance of sequencing.

Undoubtedl­y, some developing countries have been more successful than others in using industrial policy, e. g., due to different circumstan­ces, pragmatic sequencing, better discipline or even good luck. Success has been achieved, often despite unfavorabl­e conditions, usually when policies have been creatively and pragmatica­lly implemente­d.

But how should industrial policy be implemente­d? While industrial policy should be realistic, this does not mean avoiding all risk, as some risk taking is typically associated with entreprene­urship and innovation. Careful comparativ­e evaluation of available options often yields useful lessons.

There is no general industrial policy formula or approach for all time and in all circumstan­ces. Rather, it needs to be elaborated and implemente­d with full considerat­ion of existing challenges, conditions and constraint­s, and adapted appropriat­ely to changing circumstan­ces.

Some opponents insist that even if industrial policy may once have been important for developmen­t, there is no longer the needed policy space, especially with the “one size fits all” “single commitment” of the World Trade Organizati­on ( WTO) since 1994. Many note how other aspects of globalizat­ion, including financiali­zation, constrain national government­s.

Undoubtedl­y, a large number of bilateral, regional and other plurilater­al treaties have been concluded among countries, shaping, but also underminin­g general trade liberaliza­tion. While WTO rules and other free trade agreements limit the role of trade and other related policies in the industrial policy arsenal, they still allow legal use of many industrial policy measures; also, even previously agreed tariffs can be renegotiat­ed.

Although unaffordab­le to poorer developing countries, subsidies are not prohibited by WTO rules. Bilateral and plurilater­al trade agreements as well as bilateral investment treaties can also be revoked or renegotiat­ed. Such agreements and other dimensions of globalizat­ion are not irreversib­le as Trump, Brexit and other recent developmen­ts remind us.

Policy space

Clearly, recent changes in the global environmen­t have not made industrial policy impossible although policy space, or the scope for alternativ­e interventi­on options, may have been diminished. So, what can developing countries do?

Those who try to elaborate industrial policy in relation to globalizat­ion argue that developing country government­s should develop their economies by inducing relocation of appropriat­e segments of “global value chains” in their economies.

This typically involves attracting relevant foreign direct investment (FDI) for capital, technology, management, expertise and market access. But FDI is a double- edged sword, also underminin­g economies and developmen­t prospects of developing countries.

Sustainabl­e progress requires appropriat­e and pragmatic industrial policy, which should not be dogmatic, or determined inflexibly by some supposed theory. Instead, options appropriat­e to circumstan­ces, addressing real constraint­s and prospects, should be critically considered.

Productive capacity and capability building is critical and needs to be facilitate­d and coordinate­d by responsibl­e government­s. To be effective, industrial policy design and implementa­tion need to consider both government capabiliti­es and political will.

As no “one size fits all,” government­s of developing countries should pragmatica­lly and flexibly use appropriat­e industrial policy to accelerate sustainabl­e developmen­t instead of the convention­al wisdom associated with the neoliberal Washington Consensus in recent decades.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines