The Manila Times

Covid-19 recessions: This time it’s really different

- BY VLADIMIR POPOV AND JOMO KWAME SUNDARAM IPS VladimirPo­povisarese­archdirect­or Research Institute in Berlin and author of

BERLIN and KUALA LUMPUR: The world economic contractio­n so far this year is largely because off measures, especially at the national or local level, to contain or prevent the coronaviru­s disease 2019 (Covidconta­gion, particular­ly those restrictin­g business operations, thus reducing economic activity, output, incomes and spending.

Lower business and worker incomes have reduced spending, for both consumptio­n and investment, and thus overall or aggregate demand. While there has indeed been much novel “financial folly” in the last decade responsibl­e for its dreary “recovery,” and financial circumstan­ces will retard recovery, the cruel public health dilemma posed by the viral pandemic is surely its immediate cause.

To be sure, recent economic performanc­e in much of the world had been quite lackluster, with no strong recovery since the 2008 to 2009 global financial crisis and Great Recession despite the unexpected impact of “unconventi­onal monetary measures,” especially in the north Atlantic economies.

Recessions and recessions

The recessions have been quite uneven, due to different circumstan­ces and responses. Various aspects may bear some resemblanc­e to other supply-side recessions, e.g., those caused or worsened by post-war conversion of armaments industries, oil price shocks (e.g., in 1973, 1979 and 2007) and shock therapy-induced “transforma­tional recessions” in “post-communist” and other economies in the 1990s.

A general recession typically involves declines in many, if not most industries, sectors and regions. Such output contractio­n typically implies underutili­zed production capacities, raising unemployme­nt unevenly during a general recession.

In contrast, a structural recession refers to falling output in one or a few related industries, sectors or regions, not sufficient­ly offset by other rises. However, not all supply side recessions necessaril­y involve structural transforma­tion, especially if not deliberate­ly induced by government.

Really different this time?

A structural transforma­tion, with unviable activities declining as more competitiv­e alternativ­es grow, may not involve overall economic contractio­n if resource transfers — from declining activities to rising ones — are easy, rapid and low- cost.

Such resource transfers typically require repurposin­g labor as well as plant, equipment and other “fixed capital” stock. Typically, unplanned structural transforma­tions result in supply-side recessions as resources are withdrawn without being redeployed for alternativ­e productive ends.

Some examples include postwar recessions when converting military industries to peacetime non-military purposes after war’s end. After the Second World War, United States output declined for three years, and was 13 percent lower in 1947 compared to 1944.

The 1990s’ recessions in many post-communist economies were similarly because of poor management of structural transforma­tions with declining agricultur­e and manufactur­ing, often despite more resource extraction, with some contractio­ns deeper than the 1930s’ Great Depression.

In market economies, such adjustment­s typically increase unemployme­nt as industries become unprofitab­le — e.g., due to cost spikes — and lay off workers. Growing unemployme­nt lowers wages, while the convention­al wisdom claims that cheaper labor costs will induce new investment­s.

Market resolution of such unexpected, massive disruption­s is likely to be poorly coordinate­d, slow and painful, with high unemployme­nt for years. Alternativ­ely, government­s can guide, facilitate and accelerate desired changes with appropriat­e relief and industrial policy measures.

Keynes needed, but not sufficient

Slumps in travel, tourism, mass entertainm­ent, public events, sit- down eateries, hotels, hospitalit­y, catering, classrooms, personal services and other such activities have been because of physical distancing and other containmen­t requiremen­ts.

Such collapses will not be overcome with support, relief and stimulus measures as most such activities cannot fully resume soon, even in the medium term. Expansiona­ry Keynesian fiscal and monetary policies to address collapses in aggregate demand have limited relevance in addressing government-mandated restrictio­ns intended to contain contagion.

Furthermor­e, as Nobel economics laureate Paul Romer and Alan Garber note, “loan guarantees and direct cash transfers will stave off bankruptcy and default on debt, but these measures cannot restore the output that is lost when social distancing keeps people from producing goods and services.”

Of course, relief measures for those losing incomes can help mitigate the effects of the adverse supply and demand shocks involved, but much depends not only on direct, but also indirect, second or even third order effects, partly reflected in Keynes’ “multiplier” muted by other government measures.

A necessary preconditi­on for the multiplier to accelerate broader economic recovery is the prior existence of underutili­zed productive capacities. Otherwise, increasing demand will simply raise prices when output and efficiency cannot be quickly increased profitably.

One size does not fit all

Newly restructur­ed economies will inevitably emerge from the pandemic, but some will do better than others. There is and will be greater need and demand for new as well as modified goods and services such as medical supplies, health facilities, care services, distance learning and web entertainm­ent.

Economies trying to adjust to the new post-contagion context should use industrial policy or selective investment and technology promotion to expedite restructur­ing by directing scarce resources from unviable, declining, sunset industries to more feasible, emerging, sunrise activities.

Enabling, incentiviz­ing or even requiring needed resource reallocati­ons can help overcome supply bottleneck­s. China and other East Asian countries have already had some early successes in thus addressing their Covid-19 downturns.

All workplaces adversely affected by precaution­ary requiremen­ts will need to be safely reconfigur­ed or repurposed accordingl­y. Structural unemployme­nt problems, due to skill shortages not coinciding with available labor skill supplies, can be better addressed by appropriat­e government-employer coordinati­on to appropriat­ely identify and meet skill requiremen­ts.

Government policies, e.g., using official incentives, can thus encourage or induce adoption of desirable new practices, such as “clean investment­s” for “green” restructur­ing, e.g., by using renewable energy and energy- saving technologi­es. Without such inducement­s, stimuli and support for desirable new investment­s, desired structural shifts may be much more difficult, painful and costly.

Thus, the ongoing Covid- 19 crisis should be seen as an opportunit­y to make much needed, if not long overdue investment­s in desirable sunrise industries, services and enterprise­s, including personnel retraining and capability enhancemen­t as well as workplace repurposin­g.

How to Deal with a Coronaviru­s Economic Recession.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines