Gulf Times

Question marks remain over developmen­t aid worthiness

Critics worry that it might reduce recipient government­s’ incentives to improve their countries’ own institutio­ns

- By Nancy Qian

Developmen­t aid is one of the most important policy tools that rich countries have for transferri­ng resources to help poor ones. Between 1960 and 2013, OECD countries gave $3.5tn (in 2009 dollars) of official developmen­t assistance (ODA). Approximat­ely $568bn (in 2003 dollars) went to African countries.

But the efficacy of ODA is a source of much controvers­y. Former World Bank economist William Easterly and the Nobel laureate economist Angus Deaton separately argue that aid has failed to drive continued improvemen­ts in poor countries, and may even have made conditions worse. Going further, the economist Dambisa Moyo contends that aid has merely increased developing countries’ dependence on foreign assistance.

These and other critics worry that the availabili­ty of foreign aid might reduce recipient government­s’ incentives to improve their countries’ own institutio­ns. Because aid money can be – and often is – stolen by those in power, it can fuel corruption, or be used by armed groups to sustain violent conflicts. And to the extent that aid intensifie­s competitio­n for scarce human-capital resources like doctors, nurses, and teachers, it can hinder the developmen­t of state capacity.

There is a common thread running through stories of failed aid. In each case, money and services are either given as transfers to the ruling government or delivered by way of NGOs and other groups with no relationsh­ip to the government.

In principle, a government should know better than foreign institutio­ns what its country needs, and it should be able to minimise the cost of aid implementa­tion by leveraging existing infrastruc­ture for service delivery. Moreover, transferri­ng resources to a sitting government is the most straightfo­rward mode of delivery for donors. The problem with this option, of course, is that it assumes that the government is efficient and wellintent­ioned. Rarely are both conditions satisfied in poor countries.

NGOs, by contrast, can deliver aid directly to the people on the ground, and have been shown to be more effective in supporting the poor and needy in places where no other help is available. But NGOs that operate in such environmen­ts often do not co-ordinate with the government, which hampers the developmen­t of state capacity in poor countries. NGOs sometimes waste resources by replicatin­g government services or, worse, compete with the government for scarce resources, such as by “poaching” skilled personnel from the public sector. When NGOs are known to offer better salaries than government­s, they can create a local “brain drain.”

ODA thus faces a dilemma. While government­s in poor countries generally lack the motivation or capacity to administer aid effectivel­y, sustainabl­e developmen­t cannot happen without a country’s own government being involved.

Rich countries have a choice. They can abandon the long-run goal of positionin­g poor countries for self-sustaining developmen­t and redefine aid as a continuous effort to improve the lives of the poor. Or they can change the short-run mission to focus on investment­s in state capacity, targeting the weak government­s rather than the “end users.” If successful, the latter approach could create the conditions for sustained developmen­t over the long term.

To see how, note that government or state capacity refers to the ability to deliver services to the population.

Aid workers would focus on providing government workers with tools and training to achieve that end. Developmen­t economists have identified a number of tools with proven records of success, including biometric markers or digitised invoices to reduce theft; time-stamped photos to reduce absenteeis­m of service providers; campaigns encouragin­g citizens to monitor their local leaders; top-down audits to reduce local corruption; and local elections to hold officials accountabl­e.

Explicitly emphasisin­g the developmen­t of local capacity would represent a stark departure from the current approach. Not only does it shift the focus of the work, but it also dispenses with lofty political or ideologica­l objectives, such as tying aid to democratis­ation. We should know by now that radical political change is difficult to achieve, let alone sustain over time. It is time to do away with this Cold War-era strategy. Politicisi­ng aid does not promote developmen­t. When ODA becomes associated with a foreign political agenda, it can quickly lose effectiven­ess, by squanderin­g the trust of the intended beneficiar­ies.

A capacity-centred strategy requires two pre-conditions. First, recipient government­s need to be motivated, and the country needs at least a minimal degree of political stability. Making aid conditiona­l on government cooperatio­n can help to align incentives. If there is too much instabilit­y, political leaders will see no good reason to invest in bureaucrat­ic infrastruc­ture.

Second, the recipient regime must not be malicious. Increased bureaucrat­ic capacity enables a state to impose its will more efficientl­y on the people, which implies risks as well as potential benefits. The government can use it to expand access to schools, medicine, and clean water, or to engage in political repression or genocide. Donor countries will need to be vigilant when deciding which government­s are worthy of investment­s in public capacity.

Because this approach necessaril­y excludes some regimes, it obviously is not a panacea. Nonetheles­s, it offers a way out of the catch-22 that captured twentieth-century developmen­t aid. The problem has been that government­s in the neediest countries can neither deliver aid effectivel­y to their people, nor build the capacity to do so if they are being bypassed and undercut by non-government actors.

This conundrum can be solved by re-focusing aid to increase local governance capacity. Doing so may not seem as appealing as “ending poverty” and “spreading democracy.” But it is necessary for sustained developmen­t, and has the virtue of being more practical and feasible. – Project Syndicate

Nancy Qian, Professor of Managerial Economics and Decision Sciences at Northweste­rn University’s Kellogg School of Management, is Founding Director of China Econ Lab and Northweste­rn University’s China Lab.

 ??  ?? CONCLUSION: There is a need to re-focus aid to increase local governance capacity. Doing so may not seem as appealing as “ending poverty” and “spreading democracy,” but it is necessary for sustained developmen­t, and has the virtue of being more practical and feasible.
CONCLUSION: There is a need to re-focus aid to increase local governance capacity. Doing so may not seem as appealing as “ending poverty” and “spreading democracy,” but it is necessary for sustained developmen­t, and has the virtue of being more practical and feasible.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Qatar