Business Day

It took a woman to show how sharing collective­s survive

- TRUDI MAKHAYA Makhaya is CEO of Makhaya Advisory.

Iam working on a project that has got me thinking about the work of Elinor Ostrom, the first, and to date only, woman to have been awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. I can’t say that Ostrom’s significan­t contributi­on to economics featured much in my university studies in the subject, which I began two decades ago. Perhaps now, since she was awarded the Nobel in 2009, her work may have gained more prominence in curricula.

It is worth reflecting on the contributi­on Ostrom made to economics and political science. The short citation for the Nobel states that the award is bestowed on her “for her analysis of economic governance, especially the commons”. Her work challenged the “long, unanimousl­y held” view that “natural resources that were collective­ly used by their users would be overexploi­ted and destroyed in the long term”.

This is the famous “tragedy of the commons” principle. Ostrom applied a dizzying range of methodolog­ies to understand how small communitie­s manage shared natural resources such as pastures, fisheries and forests. She found that in certain conditions rules can emerge that allow communitie­s to use the commons in an economical­ly and ecological­ly sustainabl­e way.

Ostrom also challenged the notion of the market and the state as the ideal institutio­ns for organising private production and exchange on the one hand, and public goods on the other. She argued that this did not fully cover the diversity of institutio­nal arrangemen­ts that people develop to govern, provide and manage public goods and common resources.

What emerges from her research is how sophistica­ted some “traditiona­l” modes of organisati­on are. Recent economic thought has often portrayed communal multilayer­ed institutio­ns as backward or flawed. I am not immune to this. But to refuse to understand other organisati­onal modes is intellectu­ally limiting.

As Ostrom pointed out in her Nobel lecture: “We demonstrat­ed that complexity is not the same as chaos in regard to metropolit­an governance. That lesson has carried forth as we have undertaken further empirical studies of polycentri­c governance of resource and infrastruc­ture systems across the world.”

The “tragedy of the commons” is not inevitable. It is a logical outcome of game theory models for certain limited settings where the participan­ts do not have the shared history and/or communicat­ion mechanisms to develop agreements, norms and sanctions. But Ostrom found that there were surprising­ly numerous instances where communitie­s create effective governance.

New technologi­es require people to think, once again, about how to organise nonhierarc­hical, interconne­cted systems such as the internet, open source software, social networks or Wikipedia.

OSTROM FOUND THAT THERE WERE SURPRISING­LY NUMEROUS INSTANCES WHERE COMMUNITIE­S CREATE EFFECTIVE GOVERNANCE

Robin Chase, founder of car-sharing service Zipcar, quotes Ostrom extensivel­y in her own writing about how to govern platforms for sharing assets, including how to build trust.

Like many other discipline­s, economics has not always valued the intellectu­al labour of women. In her early career, Ostrom was blocked at every turn. She had to be multidisci­plinary because, at first, economics programmes would not admit her. In choosing her niche, it is possible that she was driven to the most neglected reaches of the field, where she could work in peace. Ostrom went on to produce phenomenal research — a cautionary tale on what ideas sexism might have robbed the world of.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa