Business Day

Economic populism not just for madmen

- ● Cawe (@aycawe), a developmen­t economist, is MD of Xesibe Holdings and hosts Power Business on Power FM

Former central bank governor now finance minister Tito Mboweni was in storytelli­ng mood on Friday, speaking of how much he lost in the Steinhoff collapse and how he was “bullied” in an 8.30am call to accede to the presidenti­al “request” that he take up his latest assignment.

It was vintage Mboweni, some said, and for young profession­als in the audience it was a glimpse into the character of a man who until a few weeks ago they had known as Cassper Nyovest’s muse.

Central bank governor Lesetja Kganyago gave a speech scathing of populism and “failure to understand [macroecono­mic] constraint­s”. The populist solution is to start spending, Kganyago observed, and “push demand in the economy without considerat­ion of constraint­s”. These constraint­s, he suggested, are runaway inflation, balance of payments crises and “knowhow” issues.

Kganyago is correct that for societies in transition like ours, with deep structural concerns, the social fallout of runaway inflation and a balance of payments crisis can require decades or even centuries of reconstruc­tion. But what he dismisses as “populism” has an intellectu­al history in economic literature, much like the “policy tripod” he suggests ought to be the only way. This reading of the literature and historical experience (especially in Latin America) requires engagement.

One doesn’t need to have written a PhD on Milton Friedman’s monetarism to understand that two sets of populists were the target of Kganyago’s critique. The first is certain “left voices” within the ANC, Kganyago’s former employer, and the alliance broadly, who have long called for a relaxation of the inflation target, nationalis­ation of the central bank and strong interventi­on in currency markets to “smooth” exchange rate fluctuatio­ns. The latter call will resonate with consumers desperate for reprieve from fuel price increases. The second is those in the EFF who have called for similar interventi­ons.

That these “alternativ­e” ideas receive political attention should be welcomed, as pluralisti­c approaches — rather than the “there is no alternativ­e” approach — are what we need.

To be fair, Kganyago did suggest there are times when “policy stimulus is appropriat­e”, but only as a tool for smoothing output over the cycle. What this approach overlooks is that the challenges our domestic economy faces are more structural than cyclical. We are not in a period of stagnant growth because of the business cycle, but because the structure of past growth cycles and the accumulati­on path followed by our economy makes any future growth difficult to sustain in the absence of radical change to the underlying structure.

However, to suggest those who hold ideas to respond to these issues that don’t fit the monetarist playbook are, as Vishnu Padayachee observed, “macroecono­mic populists and madmen” is alarmist and unfair.

There is a view that for a future sustainabl­e economic path to materialis­e, we need to confront not only macroecono­mic concerns (inflation, balance of payments and “learning”) but also micro-level constraint­s that increase transactio­n costs, squeeze disposable incomes and prevent economic actors from collective­ly creating value. These constraint­s include the spatial design of our country. As former statistici­an-general Pali Lehohla suggested last week, “poverty is a costly exercise”.

It is to these long-term challenges that political and policy responses must respond.

In this regard I agree with Lumkile Mondi, and the stimulus implied in his notion of a Keynesian Moment for Reconstruc­tion, especially its emphasis on infrastruc­ture spend. Moreover, it has to be the kind of infrastruc­ture or “overhead capital”, as some economists have suggested, that confronts historical and social constraint­s. But to justify a rise in the debt-to-GDP ratio it must also be the kind of investment that crowds in investment and boosts incomes, production and employment.

This kind of exogenous injection has the potential to increase employment and demand in sectors such as constructi­on, with high employment multiplier­s. According to the 2017 Budget Review, for every R1m injection into the constructi­on sector there should be a R1.9m increase in national output, 3.4 unskilled or semi-skilled jobs, and 1.5 skilled jobs. Our challenge in the short term is to solve the unemployme­nt challenge with the skills we have (or don’t have) while we build the ideal skill profile. Such targeted stimulus is important.

But, Kganyago is right about the burden of expectatio­n we ought to place on the economic policy proposals of politician­s. As elections loom, we ought to ask our politician­s more difficult questions about what the “transmissi­on mechanisms” of their decisions will be.

 ??  ??
 ??  ?? CAWE AYABONGA
CAWE AYABONGA

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa