Business Day

Quantitati­ve easing could help solve SA’s economic and pandemic crises

Bank should be allowed to buy more government bonds and securities to support liquidity of banking system

- Christophe­r Malikane

Some analysts including myself have argued that the SA Reserve Bank should have long started the local version of quantitati­ve easing (QE), which involves the central bank buying long-term securities on a large scale. In addition, and contrary to the Bank’s initial position, I have argued that the law allows it to directly finance the fiscal deficit, and it could refinance government debt to open fiscal space for an effective response, not just to the Covid-19 outbreak but also to the underlying structural economic crisis.

I estimate that the limit imposed by the SA Reserve Bank Act implies that the Bank’s balance sheet could absorb at least R239bn worth of direct bond purchases from the government. This excludes loans and other advances the Bank could extend to developmen­t finance institutio­ns and municipali­ties. The limits in the act do not provide sufficient flexibilit­y and space for the Bank to play its developmen­tal role, given the scale of the structural historical problems, which have not been adequately addressed for far too long. The finance minister should by now have tabled amendments to the act to lift those limits, with new provisions that would permit the Bank to broaden the types of securities it may acquire in response to the crisis.

There are, however, those who oppose these proposals. The first view is that QE is strictly applied when economies face deflation, which is an absolute fall in prices, and when short-term interest rates are at 0%. The argument is that in deflation people delay buying goods and services in anticipati­on of prices dropping. This and other forces, such as debt deflation, reinforce a fall in demand and drive the economy into a severe contractio­n. Because the short-term interest rate is impotent at 0%, the use of QE aims to raise inflation, to make people anticipate a rise in prices in future and buy goods and services now.

The second view holds that outright financing of fiscal deficits and refinancin­g of public debt by the Bank would undermine the central bank’s “hard-won central independen­ce”, which would weaken its ability to meet its monetary policy mandate. The argument is also that money creation to finance deficits would cause inflation to breach the Bank’s target, in much the same way as QE.

The argument that direct financing of the government undermines central bank independen­ce is not necessaril­y correct. First, whether central independen­ce is undermined depends on how the interface between the central bank balance sheet and that of the government is designed, particular­ly the need for transparen­cy, accountabi­lity and the specificat­ion of limits in the use of such financing mechanisms.

Second, if the monetary policy mandate of the central bank — the inflation or long-term interest rate target — provides an explicit overarchin­g device to co-ordinate fiscal and monetary policies, the ability of the central bank to achieve its monetary mandate will not be jeopardise­d. In fact, it may be enhanced. Third, in this arrangemen­t the Bank remains independen­t to choose whatever instrument it deems fit to pursue its mandate.

In a number of cases central banks that directly finance their government­s exhibit a higher degree of independen­ce than the Bank. The Bank of Thailand directly subscribed to a variety of government debt instrument­s, yet it scores substantia­lly higher than the Reserve Bank when it comes to independen­ce.

The same is true for the Bank of Korea, which lends directly to its government. The central banks of Uganda, Nigeria and Malawi all score better than the Bank on independen­ce, and directly purchase bonds and make advances to their government­s. This is also the case with the Central Bank of Cuba, which exhibits more independen­ce than SA’s Bank.

The argument that direct money financing of the government necessaril­y undermines “the hard-won independen­ce” of the Bank is therefore not correct. It all depends on the institutio­nal design, transparen­cy and accountabi­lity in the interface between the Treasury and the central bank. The proposals for the Bank to adopt unconventi­onal measures do not tamper with the requiremen­ts for transparen­cy and accountabi­lity.

SOVEREIGN RISK PREMIUM

The second view maintains that short-term interest rates, those that are charged for lending for less than one year, should be 0% before QE can be applied. I have argued elsewhere that this view is erroneous for an emerging market. To have a stable exchange rate, the short-term interest rate in an emerging market should equal the interest rate of an advanced economy plus a sovereign risk premium. When the advanced economy hits a 0% lower bound, the emergingma­rket interest rate will equal the sovereign risk premium, which is not 0%.

Therefore, while the advanced economy embarks on QE at a 0% interest rate, the emerging market does so at some positive rate equal to the sovereign risk premium. It is wrong to expect SA to hit 0% interest before QE can be pursued. By extension it is also incorrect to say the currency will automatica­lly depreciate if QE is implemente­d. It depends on the specific aims and design of the QE.

A related argument against the QE proposal is that it is strictly for economies on the verge of a deflation. This is also not correct. When an advanced economy hits its inflation target, say 2%, the emerging market hits its own target of say 4.5%. Now if the advanced economy hits 0% inflation, the emerging market reaches 2.5% inflation. Therefore an inflation rate that is on, or below, the target and an interest rate that is at the sovereign risk premium are sufficient conditions for an emerging market to embark on QE. This is where SA is now.

To expect the emerging-market inflation rate to be on the verge of 0% before embarking on QE is to allow the unemployme­nt rate to soar to high levels because demand would have to fall significan­tly to pull inflation down to zero. Such a haemorrhag­e of the real economy would be made worse if inflation expectatio­ns are anchored, as they should be, at the target.

The Bank should not be shy to acquire more government bonds and other securities to support the liquidity of the banking system, even if the short-term interest rate is above 0%. The R11bn purchases of government bonds is a step in the correct direction, but it is sadly inadequate.

Because the banking system is increasing­ly facing defaults and high risk aversion, the Bank should be legally empowered to broaden the types of securities it could purchase from the entire financial system, to effectivel­y secure financial stability and drive progressiv­e structural change. The Bank should also explore more channels of credit transmissi­on to the real sector, beyond the convention­al banking channel, such as direct lending to developmen­t financial institutio­ns, securitise­d commercial loans, acquisitio­n of government-guaranteed securities and direct lending to government. All this should be done in a transparen­t and accountabl­e manner, in much the same way as the budget process.

In short, a new financial architectu­re needs to be establishe­d that is informed by a vision and mission to address the historical and structural fault lines of SA society, beyond the pandemic. ● Malikane is associate professor in the School of Economics and Finance at Wits University.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa