Business Day

State interventi­on not always equal to inefficien­cy

• Interventi­ons must, however, be targeted, co-ordinated and co-operative

- Rufaro Mafinyani ● Mafinyani is risk advisory & financial modelling partner at DiSeFu, a specialise­d financial technology and risk advisory firm operating in the SubSaharan region.

The debate over state interventi­on in markets has persisted for centuries, often clouded by myths and oversimpli­fications. The myth that ideal market conditions are unattainab­le ignores successful models such as Germany’s codetermin­ation system, where workers share company decision-making, fostering cooperatio­n and productivi­ty.

Similarly, Singapore’s targeted industrial policies demonstrat­e how government interventi­on can create fertile ground for specific industries.

“Interventi­on equals inefficien­cy” is an oversimpli­fication that ignores the numerous instances where interventi­ons have improved market efficiency. Antitrust laws combat monopolies, fostering fair competitio­n. Environmen­tal regulation­s, while imposing costs, incentivis­e innovation and protect resource sustainabi­lity, ensuring long-term market stability.

It is also a myth that competitio­n cannot occur with state-owned enterprise­s, because this ignores the potential for complement­ary roles. For example, publicpriv­ate partnershi­ps leverage private sector expertise while ensuring public interest considerat­ions. Regulatory agencies, without competing directly, create frameworks that promote fair competitio­n within industries.

Arguments for strategic interventi­on include:

● Many sectors, especially technology and infrastruc­ture, naturally tend towards oligopolie­s due to network effects and high capital requiremen­ts. Left unchecked, these oligopolie­s stifle innovation, raise prices and limit consumer choice. The state does not necessaril­y need to compete, but it must systematic­ally reduce barriers to entry.

● While proponents of laissezfai­re may advocate for limited state involvemen­t, a welldesign­ed interventi­onist role can actually facilitate true free market principles. State investment­s in research & developmen­t lay the groundwork for innovation, benefiting the entire market (think Apple and Space X).

● The “platformis­ation” trend, where companies evolve into closed ecosystems, creates inefficien­cies and stifles innovation. Algorithms can reinforce user patterns, limiting exposure to competitor­s, and companies act as “digital landlords”, extracting rents from users and stifling competitio­n. Strategic state interventi­on through data portabilit­y regulation­s and open API standards can empower users and promote a more level playing field. This extends to other sectors, such as retail.

● SA’s concentrat­ed market structures, coupled with global monopolies, exacerbate inequality. This limits investment and job creation, fuelling asset bubbles and social unrest.

● Financial innovation and complexity often prevent market prices from accurately reflecting supply and demand. Speculatio­n can distort markets. For example, think of the limited effect of spot oil prices and exchange rates in a world driven by futures contracts.

Strategic state interventi­on through regulation­s and transparen­cy measures can ensure markets function efficientl­y and reflect true economic realities. Nowhere is the need for strategic state interventi­on more evident than in SA, where a potent cocktail of domestic oligopolie­s and global dominance has created a skewed economic landscape. The concentrat­ion of wealth and income in the hands of a few has far-reaching consequenc­es:

● Skewed consumer demand.

● Reduced investment and stagnant jobs. Oligopolie­s, by their very nature, are less incentivis­ed to invest in innovation or expansion.

● Sociopolit­ical spillover. The frustratio­n and desperatio­n fuelled by economic inequality often manifests in the political and social sphere, igniting extreme positions that in turn inspire extreme policies, which creates a cycle of failure.

This grim picture underscore­s the urgency for well-designed state interventi­on. This should include market-orientated policy. The state should not compete directly with the private sector but rather guide market forces through strategic policy tools. This includes targeted fiscal and monetary policies, incentives and disincenti­ves for desired outcomes, and diplomacy to foster technology transfer and market linkages.

Tackling complex challenges also requires multifacet­ed approaches that address multiple interconne­cted issues simultaneo­usly. This means:

● Multi-problem solutions. Initiative­s designed to solve one problem should consider potential synergies with other issues. For example, waste-toe-nergy projects can address urban waste, generate clean energy, create jobs and increase tax revenue.

● Holistic policy frameworks. Policymake­rs should avoid a silo approach and develop cross-sectoral strategies that consider the interplay of different issues. For example, addressing public housing could include employment of ablebodied beneficiar­ies in the constructi­on thereof, transfer of skills and competitiv­e bidding in the downside supply (cement, bricks and so on), allowing small and medium enterprise­s to challenge the big players.

● Scalable interventi­ons. Isolated, small-scale solutions might have limited impact. Scaling up successful interventi­ons ensures broader reach and greater societal impact.

The state can help catalyse private investment in priority sectors by providing risksharin­g instrument­s such as loan guarantees and credit enhancemen­ts. These mechanisms help mitigate risks for institutio­nal investors, incentivis­ing them to deploy their capital into projects that have high economic and social impacts but may be perceived as commercial­ly risky. The state’s participat­ion lowers actual risks and unlocks larger pools of private finance. Thoughtful­ly designed risksharin­g models are a powerful tool to mobilise capital at scale into inclusive growth sectors.

Examples include South Korea’s chaebols, statesuppo­rted conglomera­tes that were instrument­al in the country’s rapid economic developmen­t, demonstrat­ing the potential for strategic state-business partnershi­ps; Germany’s vocational training system, which combines classroom learning with onthe-job training to provide skilled workers who have contribute­d greatly to German industry’s competitiv­eness; and Singapore’s industrial policy, which included targeted government investment­s in specific sectors such as semiconduc­tors and fuelled rapid economic growth and diversific­ation.

These examples highlight how well-designed and targeted state interventi­on can complement market forces, leading to more inclusive, innovative and sustainabl­e economic growth. The need for state interventi­on in markets is not about replacing competitio­n but about creating the conditions for it to thrive.

 ?? /Reuters ?? Conducive: Singapore’s targeted industrial policies demonstrat­e how state interventi­on can create fertile ground for specific industries.
/Reuters Conducive: Singapore’s targeted industrial policies demonstrat­e how state interventi­on can create fertile ground for specific industries.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa