Business Day

Higher for longer rates could mean a better for longer SA

- Osagyefo Mazwai ● Mazwai is investment strategist at Investec Wealth & Investment Internatio­nal.

On the morning of the budget, I wrote an article that called for the Treasury to use the gold & foreign exchange contingenc­y reserve account (GFECRA) to reduce SA’s debt burden.

This was premised on the idea that a reduction in debt would lead to lower interest payments and less need to raise government debt. This would in turn put us on a more sustainabl­e fiscal path and unlock cash flow for spending on delivery of basic services and infrastruc­ture investment.

It was clear from the finance minister’s speech that the state is committed to dealing with SA’s debt problem. There was also a clear commitment to reducing the sovereign risk premium placed on SA given our malignant structural issues. While the initiative was well received, the question now is: how realistic are the budget’s expenditur­e projection­s? And what is the outlook for continued primary surpluses and a lower budget deficit?

We have many issues confrontin­g us that require fiscal support, not the least of which are the state-owned enterprise­s (SOEs). This is the reason ratings agency Fitch stated categorica­lly that it was “cautiously optimistic” about the budget. But before we get too excited, perhaps we should be a bit more circumspec­t.

What is now grabbing headlines is the propositio­n by the Treasury that will allow the SA Reserve Bank to continue to explore lowering the inflation target range (now 3%-6%). It has had mixed reviews, but if one were to consider the overall objective of the Bank’s mandate and consider who bears the brunt of high inflation, perhaps we ought to be more considerat­e.

The objective of lowering the inflation target is to ensure greater price stability and protect consumer spending power (particular­ly lowerincom­e consumers, who are most exposed to the inflation basket).

About a year ago, Stats SA released a report that explored the relative levels of inflation among different income groups.

At that time inflation for the poorest South Africans was at an eye-watering level of 11%, while the figure for the richest South Africans was a “mere” 6.2%. In essence, prices for the poor were growing at double the rate of those for the rich. In such an environmen­t there is a significan­t risk of social unrest in response to the extensive economic hardship.

Focusing on the most marginalis­ed should be of paramount importance. My first propositio­n is that a lower inflation target can have the effect of lower inflation expectatio­ns and lower inflation outcomes in the long run. This will be based on how credibly the central bank implements policies that ultimately reduce inflation to the new, yet to be determined level.

Lower inflation is good for price-setters, wage-setters and for overall price stability in the economy. It ensures better financial planning and protects consumer spending power. The goal of any consumer is to have income growth, which at the very least maintains the same quality of life.

However, to get inflation to a lower level implies that interest rates should remain higher for longer. That is the only way inflation can be anchored within a lower target range. The real question is the source of inflation, and whether elevated interest rates will have the effect of lowering that inflation.

Inflation in SA has not been demand driven, and the argument that interest rates will remain higher for longer carries less weight in such an environmen­t. The rand-dollar exchange rate and dollar price of Brent crude have been significan­t drivers of inflation, while demand remains subdued.

PROTECTION OF THE CURRENCY AND FOREIGN INFLOWS IS IMPORTANT TO THE RESERVE BANK AND SUPPORTS THE CASE FOR HIGH RATES

We should similarly keep in mind that protection of the currency and foreign inflows is important to the Reserve Bank and supports the case for high rates.

Protection of the currency and foreign flows is good for the currency and good for our sovereign risk premium — and both are good for inflation and inflation expectatio­ns. Therefore, lower inflation can offset temporaril­y high interest rates.

The idea that the Bank could keep interest rates high artificial­ly when demand is perpetuall­y under destructio­n requires greater inspection. I believe the Reserve Bank’s monetary policy committee understand­s the implicit goal of monetary policy is to enhance growth and employment outcomes.

The key point is that there are many moving parts when it comes to reducing the inflation target range. However, the underlying objective of price stability is sacrosanct, and perhaps even if the Bank has to keep interest rates higher for a little longer it will improve the prospect of better days in the long run.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa