Daily Dispatch

Overblowin­g ‘invisible hand’

-

THE study of history teaches us that context is central to interpreti­ng any idea, event or person. Context gives us a fuller account of how things emerge and why they relate to other phenomena in human history.

Typically, when context is evoked, it is to treat historical phenomena within the confines of their own, space, and culture.

What is key for the historian is to keep a delicate balance between the significan­ce of “context” and the significan­ce of that historical phenomenon in all of human history.

With this in mind it is interestin­g to read Adam Smith’s notion of the “invisible hand” within its context in his classic text, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.

In contempora­ry popular economics, Smith’s notion of the “invisible hand” is used as a metaphor to describe the way in which the combined social and economic motivation­s of people bring about markets which supply their needs and wants without the need for the heavy hand of the state to intervene.

In its popular usage, the term “invisible hand” is evoked as a metaphor of market efficiency in arguing for the minimal regulation of corporatio­ns and markets.

Smith uses the term in two of his books, rather minimally at that. In the Wealth of Nations, he only uses the term once and reading it in context is important. In the chapter entitled “Of Restraints upon the Importatio­n from Foreign Countries of such Goods as can be Produced at Home”, Smith argues against the imposition of tariffs on imported goods.

His argument is interestin­g, because it is fixed in the time and space of the late 18th century. Smith argues, in essence, that the 18th-century merchants he is observing are likely to always favour production closer to the home market because of the high logistical costs of doing business in multiple trading ports. This meant it was rational to invest in the domestic economy.

Smith argues that “every individual endeavours to employ his capital as near home as he can, and consequent­ly as much as he can in the support of domestic industry . . .

“A merchant . . . who is engaged in the foreign trade of consumptio­n, when he collects goods for foreign markets, will always be glad, upon equal or nearly equal profits, to sell as great a part of them at home as he can. He saves himself the risk and trouble of exportatio­n . . .

“Home is in this manner the centre, if I may say so, round which the capitals of the inhabitant­s of every country are continuall­y circulatin­g, and towards which they are always tending.”

He invokes the invisible hand logically from this argument: “By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectuall­y than when he really intends to promote it.”

Clearly, Smith could not conceive of the still coming world where transporta­tion and technology created the possibilit­y of living in multiple global cities and having a corporate machinery that could easily communicat­e across the globe once the telegraph was invented.

The context in which Smith wrote has now passed, and it is clear that business people and corporatio­ns have been unchained from the national context.

Technology and financial instrument­s allow corporatio­ns to accumulate and distribute capital wherever they wish – to the detriment of local industries and markets.

Read contextual­ly, one realises that the contempora­ry popular use of the term “invisible hand” is grossly distorted.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa