Daily Maverick

Competitio­n Commission faces tough task tackling Google, Meta

The issues at the hearing into the media market and digital platforms are complex, and what the watchdog decides in the end could have far-reaching consequenc­es, especially for local news media. By

- Tim Cohen

Hearings started this week on something called the Media and Digital Platforms Market Inquiry at the Competitio­n Commission. There are several aspects to the inquiry, but the heart of the investigat­ion is whether there are market features on digital platforms that distribute news content “which impede, distort or restrict competitio­n”.

Ouch. Big question. And, of course, one that is close to my heart (and salary cheque). The issues are complex because, as I hope to show, there are good arguments on both sides. I say “hope to show” because naturally, as a participan­t in the industry, I’m biased. So, please keep that in mind.

There are two issues here: one is whether by referencin­g a news article, Google and Facebook get most of the traffic gain while having to bear a fraction of the costs. Let’s call that the search issue. Then there is also the cost-benefit ratio involved in advertisin­g, especially something known in the industry as “programmat­ic advertisin­g”. Let’s call that the programmat­ic issue.

The reason for the inquiry is, essentiall­y, that the news industry is in crisis around the world. Broadly speaking, most estimates put the number of journalist­s globally down by between 20% and 40% over the past 30 years. Publishers are extremely grumpy and looking for scapegoats everywhere. Some of their arguments are legitimate; some are not.

It’s noteworthy that, in this brave new world, there have been a few winners: The New York Times, the Financial Times and The Wall Street Journal. Their common link has been that they are large internatio­nal brands for which any marginal increase in globalisat­ion was a boon. For city newspapers, magazines and television news organisati­ons, the effect has been dire.

The counterarg­ument is this: welcome to the digital world. Digitalisa­tion has revolution­ised the distributi­on of informatio­n, largely to the enormous benefit of the world. Publishing might have suffered as a result. But that is the price that we, as humanity, pay for the ability to find, say, a crankcase for a 1956 Toyota in millisecon­ds.

From a slightly more sophistica­ted point of view, it works like this: when you search Google for news about Donald Trump, it can monetise that search request in various ways, notably by charging for ranking the responses of your search and by throwing up advertisin­g around the search. But here is the thing: the publisher of the specific article on which you click can also monetise that visit. In a sense, there is a kind of mutual back-scratching going on here.

The question is: who is getting the actual scratch? The answer is pretty obvious: Google. And Facebook and Instagram, etc, etc. Google won’t publish this figure, which is suspicious in itself, but the speculatio­n is that, collective­ly, social media companies probably make a profit in the billions a year.

Distributi­on is king

A sub-response of the internatio­nal social media houses to this is that the division is typical of distributi­on operations. Distributi­on is king: it doesn’t matter how brilliant your product is; if you can’t distribute it, it’s worthless. Distributi­on pipelines in, for example, natural gas, are also enormously profitable. Welcome to the world.

But anyway, on the search issue, there is reasonable ground for compromise because essentiall­y the relationsh­ip between media owners and distributo­rs is win-win. Not so much the programmat­ic advertisin­g issue.

Take Google. It is not only a search engine, it’s also an advertisin­g channel, and in this sense it is head-to-head in competitio­n with all other online publishers. The focus here is particular­ly on Google because its owner, Alphabet, controls all sides of the advertisin­g supply chain, from supply- and demandside platforms to ad exchanges.

What does that mean? Essentiall­y, it means Google supplies services to the ad sales industry – like advertisin­g agencies – and takes a cut of each transactio­n along the way where those ads are displayed, as well as being involved in the monitoring process, which informs the prices paid by both sides.

What that has allowed Google to do is to sell advertiser­s segments of demographi­cs, like, say, Japanese men who are likely to buy a car in the next six months. The result is that Google, as an advertiser, can offer advertisin­g that costs a fraction of what it would be to advertise directly, and it will end up being much more effective because it displays the advertisin­g “programmat­ically”.

The proportion­s here are extreme: the CPM, or cost per thousand impression­s, of programmat­ic advertisin­g is perhaps 10 times better than direct advertisin­g. This is just one of the reasons there are fewer ads in newspapers.

Google offers several arguments that, to my mind, are dubious. The first is that advertiser­s love this because it works so well. Second, this is not a closed market – news groups and any others in the advertisin­g sales business can charge what they want for advertisin­g. They can also implement data management systems so that advertiser­s can specify the demographi­c they are looking for in the same way they do for Google. There is nothing to stop organisati­ons from tracking advertisin­g utility.

But the problem is that when you are the biggest buyer and seller, you have such a massive scale advantage that advertiser­s don’t use the systems other institutio­ns have created. Some of these are also free by Google and it’s very hard to compete against free.

Another issue here is that when Google positions an ad, it does so all over the place. And a huge quantity of the websites caught up in its net are bogus and designed only to be recipients of Google’s programmat­ic advertisin­g. Google says it can’t distinguis­h between a legitimate site and a bogus one, but that seems far-fetched. The fact is, it has no incentive to cut out the bad actors.

Those are the issues. But there are other problems too. The Competitio­n Commission’s job is, as always, to examine destructiv­e market dominance. If it finds this to be the case, it could impose fines on Google and Meta and the others.

But that wouldn’t help repair the harm done to media organisati­ons. Some of the benefits should flow to them, surely? This one in particular. Just saying.

 ?? Image: istock ??
Image: istock

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa