Mail & Guardian

Odds stacked against Cyril’s stimulus offer

To make it work, politician­s must stop meddling and people with expertise must be brought in

- Ivor Sarakinsky & Ebrahim Fakir

On September 21, President Cyril Ramaphosa announced a stimulus package to resuscitat­e South Africa’s ailing economy. Its major components are infrastruc­ture spending to drive growth, regulatory reform including visa regulation­s to attract scarce skills and increase tourism, expanding mobile broadband spectrum to reduce prices and position South Africa as a key player in the fourth industrial revolution and reformulat­ing the mining charter. These silver bullets appear seductivel­y pragmatic and reasonable and have been peddled as “low-hanging fruit”.

But this is less of a stimulus package and more of a “recovery and reprioriti­sation” initiative.

A stimulus package would include a combinatio­n of subsidies and industrial incentives, the declaratio­n of specialise­d economic and export processing zones, significan­t tax reforms with tax breaks for special manufactur­ing and industrial activities and low- and middleinco­me earners coupled to moderate tax increases for the very wealthy and corporates, introducin­g a policy of import substituti­on while stabilisin­g currency volatility and rand value to protect export earnings, the reimpositi­on of moderated foreign exchange controls as well as financial sector reform, and some welfare extensions through grants (potentiall­y a basic income grant).

What was announced is therefore not a stimulus package. It cannot be called a recovery and stabilisat­ion package because doing so would be a tacit admission that stabilisat­ion is required — destabilis­ation was wrought by the preceding ANC administra­tion, of which Ramaphosa was a part.

There is very little that is new in this menu of offerings. Remember former president Thabo Mbeki’s joint initiative for priority skills acquisitio­n and accelerate­d and shared growth initiative for South Africa package, followed by Ebrahim Patel’s 2010 New Growth Path, the 2012 National Developmen­t Plan (NDP) and former president Jacob Zuma’s 2015 Nine Point Plan? The government appears excellent at generating schemes to purportedl­y expand the economy and create jobs, but these schemes perpetuall­y fail and new ones are created as rapidly as the old ones fail.

The issue that needs confrontin­g is: Why do they fail?

An important part of the explanatio­n is the governance failure of adaptive autonomy. The term “adaptive autonomy” comes from informatio­n technology and computing, and means that the dynamic of code, hardware, software and design interact with and adapt to each other and the environmen­t to achieve a specific purpose.

Transferre­d to the domain of public governance, adaptive autonomy means that politics, policy, budgets, public and private institutio­ns and people, though they have their specific modes of functionin­g, need to be calibrated, regulated and aligned towards addressing societal challenges. Although there is a connected interdepen­dence between them, each needs to follow its own logic.

The point of intersecti­on between each sector’s logic is the optimal zone for societal advancemen­t. The organic unity of the individual elements that have their own operationa­l and developmen­t modes combine to form a functional and coherent yet complex unit. Adaptive autonomy in the context of democratic political and public governance requires bureaucrat­ic power, developmen­t policy and democratic praxis to interact and align with appropriat­e policy and public service practice to be able to execute solutions for society’s challenges.

South Africa is famous for the trite but meaningles­s phrase “great policy, poor implementa­tion”. The reality, though, is that, if policy is unimplemen­ted or unimplemen­table, then that policy is incompatib­le with the ensemble of infrastruc­ture (hardware) required to execute it. This may be because either one or other part of the system is misaligned and nonadaptiv­e, or lagging behind in its developmen­t and autonomy. These variables undermine overall system functional­ity.

South Africa is bedevilled by a flawed political-administra­tive interface. Chapter 13 of the NDP identifies this as a major challenge to policy-making and implementa­tion. Predictabl­y, recommenda­tions made by the NDP to remedy this have been ignored. In effect, poor politics misaligned to societal goals trumps policy management and administra­tive process, which leads to unresponsi­ve budgets and a lack of the requisite technical competenci­es for effective public sector performanc­e.

Part of the flawed interface is a direct consequenc­e of South Africa’s transition to democracy. The fundamenta­l restructur­ing of the public service and the realignmen­t of its values consistent with democratic governance necessitat­ed political dominance at the time of the transition.

So, although the public service has been transforme­d, the legacy of politics and politician­s dictating to public service managers and administra­tors has continued inappropri­ately in the context of the post-transition developmen­tal state. Frequently, public servants have also behaved corruptly on their own or on the instructio­ns of their political principals.

There is therefore a continued mismatch between the conduct of politician­s and the general system requiremen­ts for effective administra­tion, which has led to continuing dysfunctio­n. This is exacerbate­d by an army of public servants who are unenthusia­stic and immune from effective supervisio­n. This extends to political principals who wilfully approach oversight and accountabi­lity functions as joy rides and tours rather than corrective and redemptive action.

This political-administra­tive interface is skewed and compromise­d at all tiers by meddling politician­s who blur the line between political mandate and oversight, and cross over into overt interferen­ce. When public servants as agents of their political principals interpret the political mandates of their principals as their own, the problem is compounded.

This leads to obsequious compliance, especially in instances when the legitimate political mandate is distorted by unscrupulo­us politician­s, culminatin­g in either goal displaceme­nt, maladminis­tration or malfeasanc­e. In other words, what politician­s and public servants do and what gets done are not necessaril­y what society needs or wants.

A flawed cadre deployment policy by all governing parties at all levels, coupled with weak institutio­ns caused by poorly understood regulatory frameworks, a lack of regulatory enforcemen­t and the debilitati­ng complexity of regulation disempower­s and undermines appointed officials from establishi­ng their profession­al autonomy and performing optimally.

This institutio­nal instabilit­y and societal decline is not solely the result of a compromise­d political and public sector. The private sector has contribute­d to this malaise with its myopic short-term profit motive. Its inability to moderate shareholde­r value and excessive executive pay with societal needs has hindered its adaptation to the requiremen­ts of a stable and integrated society.

There are creative ways in which the private sector can demonstrat­e adaptabili­ty and retain its autonomy: by engaging in social enterprise, developing mutually beneficial niche markets and avoiding collusive and corrupt business practices while retaining profitabil­ity and balancing it with sustainabi­lity.

Ramaphosa’s stimulus package must be located within this environmen­t. It faces the challenge of public servants demonstrat­ing fidelity to their actual jobs, prudence from otherwise meddlesome politician­s and a private sector that comes to the party.

It also needs a capable state and proper government, which require the retention, recruitmen­t and return of technocrat­ic expertise for the execution of policies and programmes. This pursuit depends on a stable governing party, and not one whose internal fractiousn­ess infects the societal sphere and all aspects of public governance.

Ramaphosa’s stimulus is reactive rather than adaptive. It is ostensibly led by an economic developmen­t department with a less-than-enviable track record of achievemen­t. A sudden turnaround in the 10 months before the next election appears a dim prospect despite the pious declaratio­ns that this time things will be different.

This stabilisat­ion or stimulus package is consequent­ly clichéd, a papering over of the cracks. It is not necessaril­y policy. It lacks the preconditi­ons of consensus, commitment, coherence and capability as anchors for policy execution.

It faces the challenge of public servants demonstrat­ing fidelity to their jobs, prudence from meddlesome politician­s and a private sector that comes to the party

 ??  ?? Tall order: President Cyril Ramaphosa’s stimulus package is reactive rather than adaptive and a sudden turnaround in South Africa’s economic fortunes 10 months before next year’s election appears to be a dim prospect, write Ivor Sarakinsky and Ebrahim Fakir. Photo: Delwyn Verasamy
Tall order: President Cyril Ramaphosa’s stimulus package is reactive rather than adaptive and a sudden turnaround in South Africa’s economic fortunes 10 months before next year’s election appears to be a dim prospect, write Ivor Sarakinsky and Ebrahim Fakir. Photo: Delwyn Verasamy

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa