Sunday Times

The cost of seizing land for free

Knock-on effects are catastroph­ic, as shown in Zimbabwe’s decline

- By JOHANN KIRSTEN and WANDILE SIHLOBO Professor Kirsten and Sihlobo are agricultur­al economists and, respective­ly, the head of the Bureau of Economic Research at Stellenbos­ch University and head of agribusine­ss research at the Agricultur­al Business Chambe

● This week the National Assembly made a landmark decision to review section 25 of the constituti­on to cater for the principle of land expropriat­ion without compensati­on.

This is a marked shift in policy, and comes at a time when land reform (through both the state and market) has made more progress than experts and policymake­rs care to admit.

It is dishearten­ing that the ANC’s amendment to the EFF motion also disregarde­d the real progress made with land redistribu­tion and restitutio­n.

Ironically, this decision comes at a time when the Zimbabwean government has establishe­d a compensati­on committee under its Land Acquisitio­n Act to allow for dispossess­ed white former commercial farmers to be compensate­d for land seized 18 years ago. This raises the question why the ANC and the EFF are taking a position that their revolution­ary counterpar­ts across the Limpopo are retreating from.

If the Zimbabwean experience is not sufficient to proffer some fundamenta­l lessons for South Africa, it would be prudent to point out a number of facts that should prompt policymake­rs to reconsider the December 2017 policy decision.

The Zimbabwean experience tells us that the notion of expropriat­ion without compensati­on is a bad idea.

The Zimbabwean­s might have seized the land without compensati­on 18 years ago, but they collective­ly paid for it through eight consecutiv­e years of economic decline that led to job losses, deindustri­alisation and a loss of agricultur­al export revenues.

In 2009, economist Eddie Cross estimated the cost of Zimbabwe’s land reform at $20-billion (R237-billion). This included lost export revenues, rising food aid imports and economic growth foregone.

After unemployme­nt rates of over 90% and tepid growth in the recent past, the Zimbabwean government is going back to correct its fundamenta­l mistake. The farmers’ estimated compensati­on costs are set to amount to $11-billion.

The moral of the story is, if the government declines to compensate its commercial sector for land improvemen­ts — at the very least — then someone else will have to pay for it, indirectly.

The compensati­on effect, as we would like to call it, results in the entire economy and its citizenry paying for land seizures through lost agricultur­e export revenues and job opportunit­ies.

Let us unpack the compensati­on effect in the South African context.

First, if the constituti­on is amended to allow for land to be expropriat­ed without compensati­on, how would the law cater for the assets on the farm and improvemen­ts made to the land? The land on its own is roughly 10% of the total value of a typical farm operation, if fixed and movable assets are taken into account. Would sunk investment­s (such as general farm infrastruc­ture and other investment assets such as farm machinery) be subject to expropriat­ion without compensati­on too?

If compensati­on is due for farm assets, and not the land itself, then a technical argument arises: would it be prudent for the government to pay 90% in compensati­ng farmers for improvemen­ts to the land, in order to obtain the 10% that represents the actual land value?

Second, a complicati­on would emerge from the fact that agricultur­al land is heavily indebted. Farm debt that is linked to the actual land through title deeds used to secure loans now stands at over R160-billion.

In this case, two scenarios are worth considerin­g. One scenario is how the government handles heavily indebted land, and the question here is: if compensati­on is not due to farmers, would there be compensati­on to banks who are de facto partial owners of that land through debt? If the government exonerates itself from compensati­ng the banks, this would translate to R160-billion wiped off the books of the banks.

Another scenario is if the government commits to cover the debt associated with land, which by definition becomes expropriat­ion with compensati­on. The only difference is that the compensati­on goes to the bank rather than the farmer.

Let us assume that the government is sensible enough to compensate the commercial farmer for improvemen­ts, and the bank through debt owed by the farmers.

If it so happens that the government determines the value of infrastruc­ture and investment­s on the farms, and then uses that same value to cover the debt that is owed to the banks, there are situations that could arise where farmers receive “zero compensati­on”. There might also be situations where seized farms are insolvent, in which case the government would have to pay the banks the balance of what is owed by the farmers whose land it is seizing.

This scenario is already permissibl­e under the constituti­on and does not require an amendment of any law.

Third, the government will awaken to the realisatio­n of the extremely complex technical headaches of expropriat­ing land without compensati­on, by which time land reform will have stalled. This will lead to another wave of impatience that will seek to implement further draconian reforms to allow the government to seize land with impunity.

We saw this in Zimbabwe when commercial farmers took the government to court over land seizures; in another moment of madness, in 2003, the constituti­on was amended to nullify all those cases.

With the benefit of the Zimbabwean experience, most of which people are quick to ignore and dismiss, we learn an important lesson that needs to be the hallmark of landreform thinking in South Africa: that there is no such thing as expropriat­ion without compensati­on in a quasi-capitalist economy.

The history of land expropriat­ion under apartheid has left a sore wound that indeed ought to be corrected. However, the enduring principle of equitable and just (not necessaril­y market value) compensati­on in contempora­ry economics serves as an important reference point.

If the government seizes private property for free, someone, somewhere within the economy, will have to pay.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa