Sunday Times

Case for higher minimum pay is dangerous

It’s depressing that the jobs summit retreated into a fantasy world

- Nicoli Natrass Jeremy Seekings

The framework agreement from the jobs summit endorses the monitoring and enforcemen­t of the new national minimum wage. Ignoring the trade-off between wages and employment, it argues that this will “stimulate aggregate demand in the economy through wage-led growth”, implying that such growth will also create jobs. This is a dangerous fantasy.

Believers in job creation through wage-led growth make three dubious assumption­s.

The first is that employers can remain competitiv­e by improving efficiency without shedding jobs. In “tradable” sectors that are exposed to internatio­nal competitio­n, firms are already under pressure to increase efficiency — they don’t need to be prompted by higher wages to do so.

Much more likely, a rise in the minimum wage will result in labour-saving technologi­cal change and some firms will go out of business. The result will be job destructio­n, especially in labour-intensive sectors where labour costs account for a large proportion of total costs.

The second dubious assumption is that higher wages will boost consumer demand to such an extent that profitabil­ity and investment remain buoyant. This is most unlikely in an open economy like SA’s where consumer demand sucks in imports (even low-income consumers purchase clothes from Asia and chicken from the US) and higher wages drive up prices, thereby underminin­g competitiv­eness in tradable sectors.

Higher wages can help boost nontradabl­e (domestic) services such as hairdressi­ng and restaurant­s, but this will be insufficie­nt to compensate for the loss of internatio­nal competitiv­eness. The likely consequenc­e is a fall in profitabil­ity, investment and growth.

SA’s economy is profit-led, not wage-led. Capital accumulati­on relies on corporate savings and capital inflows (the government and household sectors are typically net borrowers). And, as emphasised by the internatio­nal expert panel on South African growth chaired by Harvard professor Ricardo Hausmann in 2006-2007, SA’s “binding constraint­s” are on the supply side, notably skilled labour shortages, infrastruc­tural bottleneck­s and investment finance — not the demand side.

Yet the zombie notion that the South African economy is demand-constraine­d and can be kick-started by higher wages refuses to die.

For example, Cosatu favoured the introducti­on of a national minimum wage at a relatively high level, justifying it with reference to the Brazilian case, the so-called “Lula moment” when economic growth, driven primarily by the commoditie­s boom, benefited also from rising minimum wages and linked social security payments during president Ignacio Lula da Silva’s second term of office (2006-2010).

There is evidence that rising minimum wages and social security payments in Brazil helped cushion the impact of the global economic crisis, create jobs and reduce poverty. But in sharp contrast to SA, this occurred in the context of very low unemployme­nt and in an economy where investment was financed largely from domestic sources. South Africans, by contrast, borrow to finance consumptio­n — and this trend worsened after apartheid.

Two published macroecono­mic analyses of the economy using simulation­s and data from the 1990s (by Gibson and Van Seventer in 2000) and 2000s (by Oranan and Galanis in 2013) concluded that wage-led growth was not feasible in SA.

Both predicted that increasing the wage share would undermine investment, growth and employment, and generate balance-ofpayments problems. A subsequent simulation by the National Treasury (by MacLeod in 2015) came to the same conclusion, notably that the South African economy “is profit/investment driven” rather than “wage/consumptio­n driven” because profits are the main source of funding for investment and wages, and because a significan­t amount of consumptio­n generated by wage increases gets spent on imports.

The Treasury model predicted that if a national minimum wage was set at 60% of the median wage (that is close to the minimum sectoral determinat­ion for domestic work) and rigorously enforced, it would result in a 2.1% fall in employment and a 2.5% fall in output.

Two Cosatu-aligned macroecono­mic modelling projects, however, continued to present an implausibl­e alternativ­e narrative that higher minimum wages would drive growth. The models assumed unrealisti­cally that higher minimum wages would boost productivi­ty, while leaving employment largely unchanged, and that any negative impacts on profitabil­ity, investment and the balance of payments would be insufficie­nt to derail wage-led growth. Yet even in these dubious models, unemployme­nt remained stubbornly high, implying that even if higher wages could fuel economic growth by boosting demand (which is unlikely), this will never amount to serious job creation. For that, a much more labour-intensive growth path is required.

Those presenting wage-led growth as a means of overcoming unemployme­nt make a third dubious assumption, that consumptio­n-driven growth will improve the employment elasticity of growth.

Even in the consumptio­n-led growth of the 2000s, SA’s employment elasticity of growth remained low, meaning that economic growth did not result in proportion­ate job creation. Trying to stimulate economic growth through raising wages is likely to reduce it further. In other words, even if the economy was stimulated to grow faster, the benefits would not reach the unemployed and the poor.

Wage-led modelling narratives depend on implausibl­e assumption­s and are inconsiste­nt with historical trends in SA.

They offer us the rosy fantasy that, this time, things will be different: higher wages will somehow translate automatica­lly and instantane­ously into higher productivi­ty, implying that savings and investment will not be undermined.

Such narratives ignore the negative impact on profits (and thus on investment), choosing instead to emphasise the benefits of lower wage inequality but without confrontin­g the fact that unemployme­nt remains high and the chances of less-skilled workers ever getting jobs decreases.

Wage growth in profit-led economies like SA typically benefits skilled workers because it encourages mechanisat­ion: skilled labour is a complement to capitalint­ensificati­on, whereas less-skilled workers lose their jobs.

It is depressing that the jobs summit retreated into the fantasy of wage-led growth rather than confrontin­g the challenges of making the economy more labour-intensive.

Nicoli Nattrass, is a professor of economics at the University of Cape Town and Jeremy Seekings is a professor of political studies and sociology at the University of Cape Town

 ?? Picture: Reuters ?? Wage-led growth is not feasible in SA. Rather, workers need a more labour-intensive economy.
Picture: Reuters Wage-led growth is not feasible in SA. Rather, workers need a more labour-intensive economy.
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa