The Herald (South Africa)

SA Reserve Bank’s independen­ce must remain untouchabl­e

- CVR Wait, Gqeberha

In The Herald a few weeks ago, Adriaan Pask wrote under the heading: “SA in reasonable position from debt-to-GDP perspectiv­e”.

Your correspond­ent confines himself to the government’s debt excluding government’s contingent liabilitie­s as guarantor of portions of the debt of some state-owned corporatio­ns.

I wish to quote only one statement from the article and then briefly comment on it.

Pask wrote: “Things get particular­ly complicate­d from a government’s perspectiv­e as modern monetary theory dictates you can take on debt as you like if you ultimately grow yourself out of your situation and repay your debt”.

In this statement thee are two catchphras­es.

First the commonsens­e truth in the condition “if you grow yourself out of your situation and repay your debt”.

The truth in this statement hinges on the question: what does the borrower do with the borrowed funds?

Classical economists from the late 18th century until the middle of the 19th century believed government­s should only borrow to deal with an emergency — Covid-19 and the contempora­ry electricit­y crisis would probably have passed their test.

In 1856, the German economist Carl Dietzel proposed a new reason for allowing the government to borrow — to establish something of lasting utility.

In today’s language lasting utility means productive infrastruc­ture such as airports, public roads, functional clinics in rural areas and research laboratori­es, not Bryntirion Estate homes, outdated ideas like a national airline, a state mine or a bloated cabinet of ministers paid with borrowed money.

The phase “modern monetary theory” is the second catchphras­e as quoted from Pask.

This theory does in fact propose that a country can take on as much debt as is preferred, but under specific conditions — I am convinced SA does not comply with one and should not entertain complylatt­er ing with the other, the one about the central bank.

The proponents of this theory are clear on the point that it is a theory applicable to developed economies, also referred to as high-income countries.

SA is not yet there. Second, it assumes a monetary system in which “the central bank is assumed to print ...what Treasury asks it to print” (Chohan, 2020).

The central bank is no longer independen­t from the government of the day.

There are economic commentato­rs who argue that the governors of several central banks have already sacrificed their independen­ce during the Great Recession of 2007/2008, and again during Covid-19 by providing additional liquidity through the purchase of government bonds on the secondary market, a process labelled quantitati­ve easing.

The difference between quantitati­ve easing and “to print what Treasury asks” is that in the former case the governor of the central bank could use personal discretion; in the case that discretion disappeare­d.

Independen­ce from political pressure is in the case of the SA Reserve Bank enshrined in the Constituti­on and in the Act on the SA Reserve Bank.

The longer that independen­ce remains untouchabl­e the better.

The status of a country’s debt-to-GDP ratio, whether far below or way above 100%, is caused by factors that ought to be well-known to the National Treasury and have consequenc­es for that country’s fiscal stability.

A statement by JM Keynes (1936), quoted in these columns before, remains true: “...the probable interactio­ns of the factors amongst themselves” must be considered — no easy task, so much more difficult when the balance in the trade-off among factors must be found.

Then not even sweeping transgress­ions of the Public Finance Management Act under the carpet, sweeping with whatever broom, brings lasting solutions.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa