The Star Early Edition

Monetary policy must serve society

-

DEBATES on monetary policy in South Africa over the last couple of decades seem to have come from a madhouse. In the 1990s the country had old discredite­d Washington consensus policies rammed down its throat, with scant regard for alternativ­e progressiv­e ideas and little or no democratic debate or public participat­ion.

Recently the public protector, Busisiwe Mkhwebane released a report that made sweeping populist recommenda­tions about the South African Reserve Bank (Sarb). The report favoured revising the constituti­on and a binding recommenda­tion for a monetary policy regime that excludes any reference to price stability. A mandate like this doesn’t exist in any comparable country with a well-developed private banking system.

To put the report in context, we want to focus on basic monetary policy principles that have been debated for centuries by serious thinkers and scholars. We also explore how South Africa can move the debate forward.

Broadly, thinkers on monetary policy range from “sound money” advocates to those concerned that money and banking must serve the productive economy – let’s call them “serve-society” advocates.

We locate ourselves on the “serve-society” side of the debate. We agree with William Lowndes who served in the British Treasury in 1695, who said that money supply must serve society. Thomas Attwood in the 19th Century, John Maynard Keynes, the trade union leader Ernest Bevin and Hyman P Minsky in 20th Century, concurred.

Unlike Mkhwebane’s report, these economists, particular­ly Keynes and Minsky, understood that currency and money markets under capitalism have a nasty tendency to be unstable. That’s why the regulatory and lender of last resort function of the Reserve Bank is so vital. (When the operations of the inter-banking lending market cease to operate, the lender of last resort is the entity – usually a central bank – that has sufficient liquidity to lend to banks.)

The Sarb has performed these roles for almost a century. There hasn‘t been a systemic banking crises since the formation of the Reserve Bank in 1921. Experts in the field, Calomiris and Haber, 2004, find that South Africa is among the most stable top 13 banking systems in the world. The Reserve Bank should take credit for much of that.

That doesn’t mean that it’s beyond criticism which is why a serious debate is needed. The debate doesn’t need to rely on the ideas of fringe adventurer­s and crackpots. There is a wealth of intellectu­al talent on monetary and central banking policy inside and outside its universiti­es. The public intellectu­als in the unions and in civil society organisati­ons have excellent ideas. Ordinary citizens should be drawn in too.

Things cannot remain as they are; so much is changing in the world of central banking and in economic life.

Sound money thinkers tend to view banking as another business, best left to the free market. Historical­ly they have preferred deregulati­on of the banking system. But since the spectacula­r collapse of thousands of banks in many parts of the world in the 1930s, and the banking and financial crises after 2008, few propose abolishing the lender of last resort function of central banks.

Sound money economists now want central bankers bound by rules, rather than allowing for discretion. But they focus on the virtues of trade and private finance. They say “serve-society” advocates worry about production, employment and growth.

Keynes was in favour of adjusting monetary and fiscal policy where necessary. He was a passionate advocate of sound banking and financial regulation as he understood the inherent instabilit­y of capitalism. He warned that getting it wrong could massively increase poverty and unemployme­nt.

In 1933 he proposed three safeguards when shifting economic policy priorities: Firstly, don’t be doctrinair­e. Secondly, he maintained that “the economic transition of a society is a thing to be accomplish­ed slowly”. And thirdly, don’t allow “intoleranc­e and the stifling of instructed criticism”. For those not in public office he offered this final piece of advice:

Words ought to be a little wild – for they are the assault of thought on the unthinking.

Convention­al notions of what central banks are, and of what they should do, face a number of challenges. For example, the processes of technologi­cal innovation, including the growth of crypto currencies like Bitcoin, are rapidly reshaping some of the core functions of central banks.

And over the last three decades a number of economic factors have forced central banks to review their roles. The events of 2008 also shook confidence in the ability of central banks to use their reputedly vast capacity and skills to predict and head off the crisis.

After the release of the public protector’s report the governor of the Sarb, Lesetja Kganyago, offered the potential space for debate about monetary policy aimed at creating a more inclusive and prosperous society and economy.

In our view, ideas must come from across the ideologica­l spectrum. And they must be debated in legitimate and properly structured forums. One place to begin the discussion would be Parliament’s portfolio committee on finance.

Other structures – such as the Reserve Bank’s Monetary Policy Forums (as proposed by the governor) and forums led by business, labour and civil society organisati­ons as well as universiti­es – need to keep up the momentum.

The debate must be guided by one objective: to improve the quality of life of the many South Africans for whom the end of apartheid has brought no real material change. It must consider the impact of change on employment, investment and growth. – The Conversati­on

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa