The Star Early Edition

A debate on constituti­onal mandate

Asks: why is the constituti­on important and is it off limits to be being amended, if people’s interests are placed first? In the light of the controvers­y sparked by the public protector on the mandate of the SA Reserve Bank, it is important to understand

-

LAST YEAR South Africa celebrated 20 years of the signing of the constituti­on of the Republic by President Mandela. Taking our cue from the common law, our constituti­on, like many constituti­ons the world-over, serves as a form of social contract. This social contract originally emanated from the agreement reached between the king and nobility and which was later extended to the people.

Those of us who study the formations of constituti­ons would also know that constituti­ons not only serve as a social contract between the governed and the governing but also as a declaratio­n that unites peoples. One of the earliest examples of the uniting purpose of a constituti­on was the Constituti­on of Medina.

This charter, drafted by the Islamic prophet Muhammad, served as a binding document between Muhammad and the tribes and families of what was later known as Medina. The document made sure to end all inter-tribal fighting between families and clans, thus institutin­g a number of rights and responsibi­lities for each community, be they Christian, Jewish, pagan or Muslim.

While the social contract and the uniting declaratio­n serves the South African context well, for our purposes the constituti­onal objective of the Greek philosophe­r Aristotle is most useful. Pre-dating the Constituti­on of Medina by approximat­ely 1 000 years, Aristotle believed a constituti­on was to be a document outlining “the arrangemen­t of the offices in a state”. In other words, he proposed the principle, followed by nearly all modern constituti­ons, of articulati­ng the role and function of each office and how they relate to each other in the state.

At the same time, it is important to understand, as most scholars have done through the ages, that constituti­ons are not static documents. They are alive and evolving; adapting to the material conditions of the societies they wish to serve. It is for this reason that, in the last 200 years, the US constituti­on has been amended 17 times. In the last 20 years, the South African constituti­on was also amended 17 times.

Note, though, that the constituti­onal frameworks of these two constituti­ons are different. In principle, it is important to note that the constituti­ons have changed and that often the most life-giving applicatio­ns of these social contracts were the court judgments interpreti­ng the constituti­onal law. Again, it is important to note that if at any stage the governed or the governing feel that this social contract is no longer relevant to the relationsh­ip between them and their material conditions, the constituti­on itself must make provision for it to be amended to remain legitimate.

Recently, much controvers­y erupted surroundin­g the remedial action proposed by the public protector in respect of the South African Reserve Bank. We do not wish to go into the details but again suffice to say that no part of the constituti­on remains untouchabl­e in being amended, if the amendment can wield a two-thirds majority in Parliament.

What the public protector has done, whatever her actions may be in the future, is to open the debate on the mandate of the SA Reserve Bank (Sarb). Given South Africa’s economic conundrum, it should be a debate that is welcomed. In fact, in light of the 2008 global economic crisis and that even South Africa’s economic conundrum is somewhat a result of that crisis, the debate surroundin­g central banks and their mandates is happening at a global level.

Recently, leading economists at the London School of Economics released an article called: Is the era of central bank independen­ce drawing to a close? The authors of the blog include Wouter Den Haan, professor of economics and director of the centre of macroecono­mics at LSE; Ethan Ilzetzki, associate professor of economics at LSE and an expert in internatio­nal finance, fiscal policy and macroecono­mics; Martin Ellison, professor of economics at Oxford and a former consultant to the Bank of England; Michael McMahon, associate professor at Warwick and an internatio­nal consultant economist for the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund; and Ricardo Reis, professor at LSE and an academic consultant of the Federal Reserve Board of New York and Richmond.

These academics acknowledg­e that, at one stage, the independen­ce of central banks was in vogue.

It would not be wrong of us to suggest that this occurred especially during the nineties when the Bank of England was made independen­t by the Blair administra­tion in the UK and South Africa’s constituti­on, guaranteei­ng the independen­ce of our Reserve Bank, was written and promulgate­d.

Coupled with this move to declare central banks independen­t, suggest these academics, were policies which aimed at inflation targeting and protection of the national currency.

However, in the wake of the economic global crisis, the central banks and their “unconventi­onal instrument­s” as well as their ability to act “with a great deal of discretion” have come under scrutiny, especially by democratic government­s and parliament­s.

Often part of these criticisms, the academics continue, is that central banks have oversteppe­d their mandate.

They go on to point out, based on a Eurobarome­ter survey, that only 30% of Germans trust the European Central Bank. In the UK, leading figures in both the Conservati­ve and Labour parties have criticised the independen­ce of the Bank of England.

While it might not be “politicall­y correct” to quote US President Trump, even he questioned the role of the US Federal Reserve Bank during the 2016 US presidenti­al election campaign. He was not far off, when even the Bank’s vice-chair, Stanley Fischer, questioned the “many current challenges to central bank independen­ce”.

These academics then report on a survey they are conducting with leading economists across Europe, in the main OCED countries, the majority of whom, two-thirds in fact, suggested that independen­ce of central banks will change in the next two years. Even more so, the survey showed that a leading argument for the independen­ce of central banks – lower inflation – was no longer convincing to these leading economic experts.

Yet what does all of this mean for South Africa? First, we must recognise that the discussion on Sarb and its mandate is not out of line with internatio­nal trends. Economists globally, as we have just seen, are discussing this matter and so should we. Second, the discussion must focus on what kind of bank we would like to see. It is absurd that an independen­t bank, primarily accountabl­e to shareholde­rs who are sometimes foreign, is dictating monetary policy that directly affects the lives of ordinary South Africans.

Twenty-three years into democracy we must ensure the people govern and that if the bank is going to be accountabl­e, it should at least be accountabl­e to the democratic­ally elected representa­tives of the people. Indeed, a balance could be found whereby the bank remains independen­t but accountabl­e to Parliament. Currently, as per the constituti­on, it only needs to consult with the Minister of Finance.

As the ANC is in election mode, it is sad to see the expediency of some parties and organisati­ons. In particular, it is sad to see the ANC’s alliance partners, Cosatu and the SACP, not coming out in support of the re-examining of Sarb’s mandate. Instead of enlivening debates and seeking ways to improve the lives of South Africans, we see crass factionali­sm at play through this political expediency. Wesley Seale teaches politics at Rhodes University

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa