Daily Mirror (Sri Lanka)

PROFESSOR MEHTA EXPLAINS PARADOX OF CONSTITUTI­ONALISING SOCIO-ECONOMIC RIGHTS

-

Talks of constituti­on-making have again come to the fore. We, Sri Lankans, have seen our fair share of constituti­on-making since the independen­ce. But it’s arguable whether such a requiremen­t really came from the citizenry or the rulers wanted new constituti­ons to cement their political power. After all, constituti­ons don’t really matter; what matters is people we elect to safeguard them. Sri Lanka’s coalition government is said to be in its last leg of doing the patchwork before presenting its new constituti­on to parliament. But the main constituen­t parties—the Sri Lanka Freedom Party and United National Party—seem to be at crossroads over key matters such as executive presidency, devolution of power, etc., which could derail the whole process. But in this whole exercise, scant attention has been given to the social and economic rights of the citizens—whether such rights should or shouldn’t be incorporat­ed into the new constituti­on in the making. These rights are the bedrock of any functionin­g democracy. A notable absentee in this all-important discussion is the civil society organisati­ons and good governance activists, who worked tirelessly for a regime change in January 2015. It appears that in their rush to push down a new constituti­on down the throats of the citizens, for reasons only known to them, they haven’t started a fruitful debate in society how to safeguard the social and economic rights of the people with or without a new constituti­on. Hence, in the absence of such a discussion, Mirror Business recently sat down with an expert in the field of constituti­onal law to inquire how best a country can safeguard the social and economic rights of the citizenry when drafting a new constituti­on. Professor Pratap Bhanu Mehta is President and Chief Executive of Centre for Policy Research, one of India’s leading public policy think tanks. He is also a political scientist who has taught at Harvard University, Jawaharlal Nehru University and New York University School of Law. Professor Mehta is a strong proponent of decoupling socio-economic rights from the whole constituti­onmaking process and leaving such rights outside the country’s main law and we asked why. These are the excerpts from a brief interview Mirror Business had with him during his visit to Sri Lanka a fortnight ago, where he met several policymake­rs including Constituti­onal Council Chairman Dr. Jayampathi Wickramara­tne.

Why does this whole talk of constituti­onalising or not constituti­onalising of the socioecono­mic rights matter a country?

The fact of the matter is that most people in democracie­s, including Sri Lanka, want the state to do certain things for them—healthcare, education, jobs, developmen­t and so on. So, it has been part of a general discussion from a very long time.

The only new thing about this discussion is that there is going to be a constituti­onal change in Sri Lanka. In this debate, the question one must ask is, ‘what is the problem we are trying to solve by constituti­onalising the socio-economic rights?’

It is fair to say in the 21st century, any state needs certain legitimacy demands. And, part of that basic legitimacy demands will have to be the provision of opportunit­ies for economic empowermen­t, right to health and education, maintainin­g the environmen­t and so forth. It is hard to imagine any 21st century state that does not have to meet these objectives.

We all agree that it is good to have best healthcare for all citizens as equitable as possible. Nobody disagrees with the need to disseminat­e education as widely as possible. Very few people would also disagree that you need some sensible labour legislatio­n.

The more specific question however is, ‘are those goals met by putting the socio-economic rights in the constituti­on rather than leaving them to the normal hurly-burley of representa­tive politics?’ Now the short answer turns out to be a very boring answer that every social scientist gives that, ‘it depends’.

And usually the answer throws up a paradox. Those countries that have achieved these goals—health, education and environmen­tal and so forth—even in the absence of constituti­onalising such rights anyway tend do even better when you constituti­onalise them.

The idea that rights can substitute for broad governance reforms needs to be challenged. If we think that constituti­onalising rights is a substitute for solving the governance problem, we are in for a rude shock

So, if constituti­onalising a right will guarantee its delivery is a false idea, why do people tend to believe otherwise in certain parts of the world?

In countries like in India—and I think it is probably true for Sri Lanka and for all the developing countries—part of the fascinatio­n of constituti­onalising more and more rights come from a sense of deep state failure.

We have a fascinatio­n with constituti­onalising because we think that in the absence of making them a justifiabl­e constituti­onal right, our legislatur­e, ministers and parliament will not create the conditions to achieve these rights.

Most countries that have achieved these rights such as social democracie­s of Scandinavi­a and advanced developed countries actually did this without constituti­onalising them. The idea that constituti­onalising these rights is a necessary condition for achieving particular goals is simply a false idea.

This context is very important. The discourse on rights in developing countries emerges from a history of state failure. We want to go to courts because legislatur­e does not give us these rights.

But the paradox is, if we live in a country where the legislatur­e does not deliver these rights in the course of a normal give-and-take style of representa­tive politics, it is highly unlikely that even if they are constituti­onalised would make them justifiabl­e. It is also unlikely to have the effective institutio­ns to deliver on these rights.

So, what are the implicatio­ns of constituti­onalising socio-economic rights, because there has to be a reason for its rejection?

The only thing constituti­onalising such rights does is, it poses a risk; first of all, it increases the power of the courts over the legislatur­e and the executive.

So, the question is that who do you want to be the final arbiter of this issue? Do you want the democratic process to be the arbiter of this issue or do you want the courts to be the arbiter?

The kinds of issues that come up in the process of judication of socioecono­mic rights are that they are polycentri­c, which involves lots of trade-offs.

If governance is generally weak, then constituti­onalising does not ensure good governance. This is the paradox. If governance is strong, then you don’t need to constituti­onalise them

If Sri Lanka spends more on social security, health or education, there is going to be trade-off. That’s a very different kind of judication process from the right to freedom of expression. Isn’t it?

Courts are typically not very good at making those trade-offs. Those trade-offs must be part of a negotiatio­n between the elected representa­tives.

So, whether it is health, education or labour, it is not just important for such a right to be an open-ended right in the constituti­on, it should very carefully put underneath a legislativ­e framework that specifies what those national laws require.

Otherwise, you risk of having the worst of nightmares where the economy is governed by the courts, power is taken away from the democratic legislativ­e process and a perverse outcome where the rights can be used more by the privileged than the poor and vulnerable for whom such rights are actually meant.

What you are saying is that the courts should not have a role to play in ensuring the socio-economic rights in a democratic process.

What I say is that in terms of socioecono­mic rights, you need to have an iterative institutio­nal learning process—which is, today you try something in education and a few years down the line, this may become invalid and it must evolve.

By nature, court is not very good in designing or governing these institutio­ns. And most importantl­y, ultimately the government has to implement whatever these rights are, whether the courts order or not.

So, if the legislatur­e and executive are not central to that process, chances are that either these court orders will go unenforced or as it has been frequently happening in India, the court passes lots of orders but that are not being enforced.

What will the court do then? It will pass a contempt notice. But even if it passes too many contempt notices, it can’t jail an elected representa­tive.

But the question is how a poor citizen can seek justice if a socio-economic right is denied to him or her, if that right is not constituti­onalised. Isn’t the court his/her final arbiter?

The kind of sentiment you are expressing is widely shared. But there is a two-part answer to that question. We are (only) sceptical about constituti­onalising these rights. We are not saying there should not be a legislativ­e framework surroundin­g them to safeguard those rights.

Number two is that, most countries that have achieved these rights haven’t had to constituti­onalise them. Even if constituti­onalised, the courts will find it hard to fashion remedies beyond a particular point.

In the case of India, we have fashioned these rights but the courts can provide only weak remedies. How many directives can the court give or you want the courts to give directing to spend this much on X and Y?

My argument is that the judiciary is not going to be able to deliver. It does not have the power of enforcemen­t. Ultimately the power of execution lies in the hands of the legislatur­e and executive.

The judiciary can enforce the rights only if there is a substantia­l political consensus.

For me to give you an example, South Africa is considered as a most progressiv­e nation on socio-economic rights in its constituti­on. After apartheid was abolished, they handed down a couple of radical decisions and celebrated.

But as the political consensus moved away because of the problems in the African National Congress (ANC), you actually find the courts becoming much more conservati­ve. They are not giving orders to the legislatur­e (anymore).

One of the things they fear is that the new ANC government will start attacking the judiciary if the judiciary goes too much against them.

In countries like in India—and I think it is probably true for Sri Lanka and for all the developing countries— part of the fascinatio­n of constituti­onalising more and more rights come from a sense of deep state failure

So, the bottom line is, constituti­onalising socio-economic rights neither guarantees their delivery nor good governance. Are we right to say so?

If governance is generally weak, then constituti­onalising does not ensure good governance. This is the paradox. If governance is strong, then you don’t need to constituti­onalise them.

If you look at radical social democracie­s around the world, they have not actually constituti­onalised these rights.

In our context, in South Asia, a lot of people look upon constituti­onalising rights as a substitute for governance.

Look, if governance is weak, bureaucrac­ies are weak, legislatur­es and executive have not delivered, if you give the courts the power, will they deliver? That’s unlikely to happen.

The idea that rights can substitute for broad governance reforms needs to be challenged. If we think that constituti­onalising rights is a substitute for solving the governance problem, we are in for a rude shock.

But there are countries where these rights are already embedded in their constituti­ons and some countries, like Sri Lanka, who may want to include them in their new constituti­ons. So, for them what is your advice to ensure effective delivery of such rights?

I think there will be some sort of socio-economic rights in any 21st century constituti­on.

My only recommenda­tion for those who are considerin­g or who have constituti­onalised such rights is, they at the same time should put in place a clear legislativ­e framework underneath it.

For an example, let’s say you have a right to health. According to the European drafting of this right, it says, “everyone has a right to preventive healthcare and the right to benefit from medical treatment under conditions establishe­d by the national law and practices”. This is the condition of the right.

So, what you need is to specify what this national law is or otherwise you will end up with the paradox where Brazil ended up with.

Brazil is a country where the right to health is most litigated. The courts are very active and tens of thousands of cases are heard every year.

My only recommenda­tion for those who are considerin­g or who have constituti­onalised such rights is, they at the same time should put in place a clear legislativ­e framework underneath it

Every study finds out now that the promulgati­on of right to health ended up benefittin­g the privileged more than the poor.

Why, because it is an unspecifie­d right to health and you can show up in courts and say you want a specialise­d dialysis machine given the decease that I have.

And if a court is dealing with the case individual­ly, it can use the right to life, right to health as a basis to grant that relief. But that relief comes at a cost.

So, the more you rely on litigation, often the privileged ends up getting these rights. Take the case of a society where it spends a lot of money to save the lives of people over 90 years old because they are privileged when the resources are scarce.

If the court decides that this plaintiff came first and you need to give him/her the Rs.2 lakh drug, at some point it will have adverse impact on provision of basic public health (to the majority).

And litigation also happens to be a very powerful process for the middle class and above.to give you another example from the Indian context is where we weakened our right to property with the rationale of helping the poor because of being able to do some land redistribu­tion.

But what eventually happened was that all the builders used the weakening of this eminent domain to construct developmen­t projects depriving the lands made available for the poor.

 ??  ?? Professor Pratap Bhanu Mehta PIC BY PRADEEP DILRUKSHAN­A
Professor Pratap Bhanu Mehta PIC BY PRADEEP DILRUKSHAN­A

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka