Daily Mirror (Sri Lanka)

Importance of savings mobilizati­on

(An article written by Dr. Nimal Sandarathn­e to mark the 45th Anniversar­y of National Savings Bank falls on 16th March, 2017)

- NIMAL SANDERATNE

The National Savings Bank (NSB) celebrates its 45th Anniversar­y on March 16th. However the antecedent­s of the Bank goes back to colonial times. On the 6th of August 1832, one hundred and seventy five years ago, the British Governor, Sir Robert Wilmot Horton establishe­d the Ceylon Savings Bank. The Post Office Savings Bank was a very important arm of this Bank in the mobilizati­on of savings island wide. On the 16th of March, 1972 The National Savings Bank was establishe­d by amalgamati­ng the National Savings movement’s Ceylon Savings Bank, Post Office Savings Bank and Savings Certificat­es Section of the Post Master General’s Department. The NSB and its predecesso­rs have been an important means of mobilising savings, especially rural savings.

This article discusses what constitute­s savings and the relevance of a proper conceptual­isation of savings for savings mobilizati­on, the importance of mobilizing savings, particular­ly rural savings and the factors influencin­g savings.

WHAT ARE SAVINGS? THE CONCEPT OF SAVINGS FOR SAVINGS MOBILIZATI­ON

Central to the problem of savings mobilizati­on is the concept of savings that has been handed down in economic theory from Marshall to Keynes and in post-keynesian economics. Economists have defined savings as a residual of consumptio­n (Savings = Income – Consumptio­n).

This equation is correct by definition. Yet, it could be misleading in understand­ing the behavioura­l aspects of savings. It does not catch the dynamics of the savings process. Defining savings as a residual implies that savings are pre-determined by the income level. If incomes rise, there is a chance for increased savings. If incomes fall, there could be a reduction in savings or dissavings. And if incomes are static, there is no prospect for increased savings.

This conceptual­isation makes savings a passive act. Consumptio­n is the primary function, while savings is a derived one. Such conceptual­isation partly arises out of the fact that often consumptio­n is a very high proportion of income. Therefore we fall into the trap of thinking that the smaller amount or proportion is a residue.

Savings is not necessaril­y a residual one. It could be a positive act, Even if saving is not a positive act in a particular society, at a particular time, it could be made an active one. Sometimes the desire to increase savings could itself increase incomes. Sometimes the desire to increase savings could reduce consumptio­n. In other words, instead of savings being a residue, the amount of consumptio­n or the level of income could be altered to accommodat­e a different level of savings.

Even in poor societies consumptio­n is elastic. People can and people do change their consumptio­n levels in order to be able to save more. There is no minimum level of consumptio­n although one could determine various levels of consumptio­n as necessary to maintain basic requiremen­ts or standards of living. People can be induced to increase savings if they see some real benefit from such savings.

Very poor people are known somehow or the other to save for a religious pilgrimage. Very poor people are willing to save to educate their children. Sometimes a new consumer durable, which is a status symbol and prestigiou­s to own, could induce poor people to cut their consumptio­n in order to be able to purchase an item such as a radio, a TV, a sewing machine, a bicycle or a torch. This is particular­ly so if there is some facility by which the investment can be made in instalment­s, by some kind of hire purchase financing. The system of rotating credit associatio­ns or Cheetu has as its fundamenta­l logic, the mobilizing of a large sum of money in small instalment­s for the purchase of a consumer durable or incurring some bulky expenditur­e through monthly voluntary savings.

All over the world, in diverse cultures, informal groups have been formed to save. These rotating savings and credit associatio­ns are well known to us as ‘Cheetus’ or ‘Seetus’. They have a remarkable similarity in very divergent cultures. Their basic features give valuable lessons on the motivation­s for saving. The basic features of these societies are that people voluntaril­y get together to contribute an agreed amount at regular intervals. The pooled amount is distribute­d as a lump sum to one of the participan­ts. The method by which a participan­t obtains this lump sum varies. Sometimes it is on an agreed order, or else the highest bidder gets it or the lottery method is used to determine the order of recipients.

Two factors are important in the motivation to form such societies. First, most societies are formed with the participan­ts having in mind a commitment to spend the amount for some specific purpose. They are a means of purchasing a desired item for which the lump sum cannot be found immediatel­y. Savings are therefore a function of planned future expenditur­es, and in most cases such expenditur­e is for consumer durables or expenditur­e like a pilgrimage.

The second important fact is that a prior commitment and obligation to save is an important factor in influencin­g people to put by a small sum. Therefore such savings appear to be both due to a prior commitment and obligation and for a specific goal in mind. If there was no commitment to a future expenditur­e, there may have been no savings.

It is generally presumed that people are deriving the highest income they could, with the given resources. This is not so. When people have additional needs, they are prepared to work more hours or take on ancillary work. If self employed, they could put forth better quality of work. By these various means there is a possibilit­y of increasing incomes.

A positive desire to save could be induced by a desire to increase consumptio­n, which could in turn increase income. Therefore the desire to increase savings could increase income. The concept that savings is a residual of consumptio­n is an ex-post formulatio­n, which is correct by definition, but misleading in either understand­ing the dynamics of the savings process or as providing guidelines for increasing savings.

A very important implicatio­n that arises from this discussion is that savings can be increased even when incomes are low and static. Furthermor­e the motivation to save could increase income. Savings are in various forms and these forms need to be channelled into the financial system. Non financial savings could be converted into financial savings in institutio­ns. A common practice in rural societies is cash hoarding. These could be channelled into the financial system by stable financial institutio­ns. The National Savings Bank and earlier the Ceylon Savings Bank and the Post Office Savings Bank performed this role.

THE IMPORTANCE OF RURAL SAVINGS MOBILIZATI­ON

The mobilizati­on of rural savings is important for economic developmen­t for several reasons. Foremost among these reasons is the fact that the rural sector constitute­s about a third of the country’s population. In order to develop a healthy and viable rural financial market, resources should be mobilized from the rural sector itself. In other words, rural savings mobilizati­on is an integral and essential component for developing a sustainabl­e rural financial market. Much of the rural sector’s developmen­t could be financed from the sector itself, if only the correct techniques, incentives and institutio­ns are provided.

However in most countries the emphasis has been on giving credit to the rural sector. Programmes are designed to give credit from government funds or persuade, cajole or compel banks to give credit on ‘soft terms’. Such programmes often tend to be corrupt, inefficien­t, irresponsi­ble, inadequate and erratic in their flow of funds.

FACTORS INFLUENCIN­G SAVINGS

Five economic conditions affect and influence savings. While these factors influence the willingnes­s and capacity to save, it is the institutio­nal factors that are discussed later that provide the facility to save. In turn the facilities to save could influence the willingnes­s and capacity to save.

Interest rates have a bearing on savings mobilisati­on. while slight changes in interest rates do not necessaril­y affect savings, high interest rates do provide an incentive to saving. there is growing evidence that interest rates do affect rural people’s willingnes­s to save. For instance, it has been shown that people shift their savings from lower interest higher liquidity savings to higher interest lower liquidity fixed deposits when the interest rates of the latter are distinctly attractive. high interest rates attract new deposits. In fact, high interest rates create an interest consciousn­ess among people - even among people who cannot calculate interest rates accurately!

It is not only nominal interest rates but real interest rates which affect savings. The real interest rate is the nominal interest rate, adjusted for inflation. It is true that people, especially rural people, don’t make fine decisions regarding the real interest rates. Yet, where there is a high rate of inflation, people are aware that financial investment­s are unprofitab­le and that it does not pay to keep cash. They may save but not in financial forms. They would buy land or jewellery or even some consumer durables whose price they know would rise quite sharply and visibly in a short time. Therefore inflation is an important factor influencin­g the willingnes­s of people to save in financial terms.

The third factor which influences the capacity to save is the income levels and the cost of living. When incomes are low and the costs of living are rising, the capacity to save is less.

The fourth factor is the availabili­ty of consumer durables. If we are willing to accept that saving is an act of delayed consumptio­n, then the availabili­ty of consumer durables, which are not affordable on current income results in people saving a part of their income to buy a consumer durable later. Therefore in a society where people are consumer oriented and think they must possess a radio, a T.V. set, refrigerat­or, sewing machine or motor vehicle, they may very well cut their current consumptio­n and save in order to enable them to purchase these.

Social and cultural values play an important role in influencin­g decisions to save. A society or people given to ostentatio­n may spend a larger proportion of their income, if not all of it, to display their wealth. On the other hand, social values may dictate others to be frugal and save for a rainy day or for their children and grand-children. It is a fact that such attitudes play an important role and particular ethnic or cultural groups can be identified as having different attitudes to consumptio­n and savings. For instance, societies which require a dowry system or possession of jewellery may save more for such needs. Therefore social and cultural values, as well as expectatio­ns of the future, are important influences on people’s propensity to save.

Institutio­nal factors have an important bearing on rural savings mobilizati­on. It is the institutio­ns and the techniques adopted by them which provide the facilities for saving. In turn, the facilities to save influence the willingnes­s of individual­s to save. It is not merely one of increasing the number of bank branches but also qualitativ­e adaptation­s suited to rural conditions that are needed for increasing savings. The type of banks that are establishe­d should be suited to the rural clientele. Bankers should go out to their rural customers rather than expect rural folk to come to them. If branch banks are of the same type as urban banks and use the same approaches in their banking, then, it is likely that such banks would attract only larger customers such as land owners, traders and merchants, rather than the larger number of ordinary rural folk. This would mean that these banks would not really have a capability to mobilize the savings of the bulk of rural people. They may dole out some finance to farmers under special agricultur­al credit programmes, but they will not really have a rural clientele who have confidence in their bank.

The techniques used by banks are of considerab­le importance on how successful they would be in mobilizing rural savings. It is often said that it is uneconomic to attract small deposits because the administra­tive costs of such schemes are not justified by the amount of savings mobilized. In this respect, the experience of the Syndicate Bank in India is instructiv­e. They commenced a savings scheme known as the Pigmy Deposits Scheme. The objective of this scheme was to mobilize small savings - in fact very small savings. Under this scheme a Commission Agent calls over at homes and accepts deposits as small as 25 cents a day. By a person calling at the door, as well by accepting such small deposits, the Syndicate Bank has been able to mobilize very large amounts under this scheme. The costs of such a scheme are kept to a minimum by employing the collector on a commission basis.

Another technique that has been adopted is to organise savings schemes among school children. Children could persuade their parents to give them money to save and the children themselves could save out of moneys that they would have otherwise spent on useless items. Such a scheme too would be of minimum cost. It could pay dividends not only immediatel­y but have an important impact in the long run by inculcatin­g the savings habit which would increase savings of adults later on.

Another possibilit­y is to attract savings by schemes which are particular­ly active at certain times of the year such as at harvest time. In a farming community, an active savings campaign at harvest time could attract money that would otherwise be spent on extravagan­t items or hoarded.

Savings could also be increased by tying the granting of credit to savings deposits. One of the important perspectiv­es in understand­ing savings is that people are willing to save when there are tangible benefits. Therefore, if a saving scheme is tied to the granting of credit and a depositor granted credit several times his deposits, such a scheme should indeed attract savings. Programmes could also be designed for the purchase of consumer durables before the entirety of the required money is saved.

A technique used by our banks to attract savings adopts and adapts a traditiona­l custom. The banks open on Sinhala and Tamil New Year day for the first financial transactio­n, for the new year. People are encouraged to transact their first business with the bank by opening a Savings Account with the traditiona­l offering of betel leaves. The bank gifts a coin in return. Many bank customers now consider it auspicious to make a deposit at their bank during the Sinhala New Year. This scheme has indeed successful­ly modernised a traditiona­l custom with successful results in savings mobilizati­on.

CONCLUDING REFLECTION

Even in low income societies people are able to save. The conceptual­isation of savings in the manner outlined earlier is crucial to a positive approach to savings mobilisati­on. Macro economic conditions such as interest rates, inflation, income levels and the cost of living, as well as social and cultural values influence the willingnes­s and capacity to save. Savings are inevitable and all societies do save. Therefore, the developmen­t of appropriat­e institutio­ns and innovative techniques for savings mobilizati­on are important determinan­ts of the amount of savings actually mobilized. Innovative techniques suited to rural conditions and cultural practices can increase the amount of savings mobilized.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka