Daily Mirror (Sri Lanka)

Evolution of production networks in Asia Pacific

- By Hubert Escaith, Satoshi Inomata and Sébastien Miroudot

As production activities became increasing­ly fragmented and relocated across borders, a number of observers started to use the expression ‘global value chain’ (GVC). The term is often used without knowing what a value chain really is or looks like. What is clear is that the GVCS, as they are usually described, do not reflect the internatio­nal production networks that we see around the world today.

In 1985, there were only four key economic players in the Asian region: Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia and Singapore. The basic structure of the production network was that Japan built up supply chains from countries such as Indonesia and Malaysia.

By 1990, the number of players had increased. Japan, the first regional giant, had extended its supply chains of intermedia­te products to South Korea, Taiwan, China and Thailand. While still relying on the productive resources of Indonesia and Malaysia, Japan also started to supply products to other East Asian economies, especially to the group known as the ‘newly industrial­ised economies’ (NIES), namely Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan and South Korea. During this phase, Japan relocated production bases to neighbouri­ng countries quickly, due to the yen revaluatio­n agreed to in the Plaza Accord of 1985.

In 1995, the United States came into the picture as the second regional giant. It drew on two key supply chains originatin­g in Japan, one via Malaysia and the other via Singapore. These two countries came to bridge the supply chains between East Asia and the United States.

In the year 2000, on the eve of its accession to the World Trade Organisati­on (WTO), China began to emerge as the third regional giant. The country entered the arena with strong production linkages to South Korea and Taiwan. It gained access to Japanese supply chains through the latter. The United States also brought a new supply chain from the Philippine­s. In this way, the basic structure of the tri-polar production network in the Asia–us region was completed.

By 2005, the centre of the network had completely shifted to China, pushing the United States and Japan to the periphery. The shift of supply chains towards China typically had a high degree of fragmentat­ion and sophistica­tion, incorporat­ing substantia­l value-added input from each country involved in the production network. The competitiv­eness of Chinese exports was not only attributab­le to that country’s cheap labour force, but also to the sophistica­ted intermedia­te products that the country imported from other East Asian economies, embedded in goods labelled ‘Made in China’.

The organisati­on of internatio­nal production networks has so far been mostly regional, producing in a given region and selling to consumers in that same region. This is especially the case in Europe, with Western Europe absorbing the manufactur­es produced in the eastern part of the continent and in North America, where the main source of final demands is the United States.

Asian picture

Asia presents a slightly different picture. The ‘supply’ part of the networks is regionally concentrat­ed, yet when it comes to the ‘demand’ side, the networks become fairly global. This configurat­ion stems from the early days of the export-led growth strategy espoused by Japan in the second half of the 20th century and later by the NIES in the 1970s. The evolution took a dramatic turn with China’s accession to the WTO in 2001. The irruption of one billion Chinese workers into the global economy had a tremendous impact on the redefiniti­on of comparativ­e advantages in the region (and beyond).

The net impact of global value chains on employment has been the subject of a heated debate in the years since the global crisis of 2008–09, in view of the high rate of unemployme­nt affecting many open economies. The debate has intensifie­d mainly in developed countries, where lower-skilled workers are exposed to higher chances of job losses. In contrast, countries with large labour surpluses and low wages have observed relatively strong job growth following their GVC integratio­n. Developed countries specialise in services, particular­ly research and developmen­t or business services, where they have so far maintained comparativ­e advantage. Employment in these countries tends to be mainly in services, with only marginal employment being generated by primary sectors. But there are exceptions. Australia, despite being a developed economy, has a strong primarybas­ed export sector.

Strength in basic commoditie­s does not always mean large employment impact: Chile, the world’s largest exporter of copper, employs relatively few in its mining sector considerin­g its gross export strength in that area. This apparent paradox reflects the fact that modern mining industries are highly capital-intensive and thus generate relatively low employment. Most of the jobs indirectly related to extracting operations are in supporting activities such as maintenanc­e, energy supply and transporta­tion, which are classified in the service sector rather than the mining sector itself. When it comes to considerin­g the performanc­e of non-exporting sectors, some firms may participat­e in export efforts indirectly by providing intermedia­te products to exporting lead firms. This mode of GVC participat­ion is particular­ly important for providers of services (which were traditiona­lly considered ‘non-tradeable’) or for small and medium-size firms which do not have the capacity to engage in global market operations. Compared with the previous import-substituti­on industrial policies that underpinne­d the developmen­t of largescale industries, the utilisatio­n of more flexible networks of second-tier suppliers is one of the distinctiv­e features of the new mode of industrial­isation. Irrespecti­ve of an economy’s developmen­t status, the exportrela­ted demand for low-skilled jobs has gone down in all countries, while demand for higher-skilled positions is on the rise.

Over the past few decades, crossborde­r production networks have evolved and continuall­y expanded according to countries’ comparativ­e advantages. This process was intrinsic to the developmen­t of Japan and China, as well as the newly industrial­ised economies in Asia. It has also shaped income distributi­on across the Asia Pacific. As Asian integratio­n goes forward, understand­ing the nature and dynamics of these production networks will be more important to securing stable and fair growth throughout the region. (Hubert Escaith is the World Trade Organisati­on’s Chief Statistici­an. Satoshi Inomata is Chief Senior Researcher at the Developmen­t Studies Centre, Institute of Developing Economies, JETRO and Sébastien Miroudot is Senior Trade Policy Analyst at the Trade in Services Division of the OECD Trade and Agricultur­e Directorat­e)

IRRESPECTI­VE OF AN ECONOMY’S DEVELOPMEN­T STATUS, THE EXPORT-RELATED DEMAND FOR LOWSKILLED JOBS HAS GONE DOWN IN ALL COUNTRIES, WHILE DEMAND FOR HIGHERSKIL­LED POSITIONS IS ON THE RISE

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka