Bangkok Post

The right way to finance disaster recovery

- By Koichi Hamada in Tokyo

● In mid-October, as Japan was being battered by Typhoon Hagibis — the most powerful typhoon to hit the country in six decades — it was also shaken by a magnitude 5.7 earthquake. As climate change progresses, Japan, like the rest of the world, will face increasing­ly frequent and severe natural disasters, necessitat­ing costly recovery efforts. Tax increases are not the way to pay for them.

Soon after the 2011 earthquake and tsunami devastated much of Japan, two influentia­l economists, Motoshige Ito and Takatoshi Ito, proposed in the Nikkei that, to avoid burdening future generation­s, the government should finance the recovery by raising taxes, rather than issuing debt. Hundreds of economists endorsed the proposal.

But the approach could not be more wrong. Indeed, it contradict­s the theory of public finance, which states that the response to temporary shocks, such as natural disasters or wars, should be financed by temporary increases in the deficit.

Increasing government revenues enough to cover the additional expenditur­e without altering the fiscal balance would require major tax hikes. Beyond the direct cost to taxpayers, this would impose indirect costs on the economy by distorting the market mechanism, weakening incentives, and underminin­g efficiency at precisely the moment when the country can least afford it.

Raising taxes to finance disaster recovery is the equivalent of imposing fiscal austerity during a recession. As the experience­s of Greece and others have starkly demonstrat­ed, making deep spending cuts during a downturn depresses income and undermines growth, making it even harder for the government to repay its debts.

Just as you wouldn’t force an injured child to carry a heavy backpack, it is unwise to burden a battered economy with higher taxes. Because natural-disaster recovery, like a recession, does not last forever, a country is better off delaying fiscal consolidat­ion until the economy is better able to weather it — that is, after a largely debt-financed recovery is complete.

When I made this argument in 2011, Japanese media were reluctant to publish it. They subscribed to the notion, pushed by the revenue-hungry Finance Ministry, that raising taxes will have the same effect, whether it happens now or in the future.

This argument rests on the concept of Ricardian equivalenc­e: a government cannot stimulate short-term consumer demand with debt-financed spending, because people assume that whatever is gained now will be offset by higher taxes in the future.

But even the concept’s author, David Ricardo, recognised that it is based on an idealised scenario, in which economic actors maintain the same objectives over a very long time horizon — longer than any human lifetime.

Over a century later, Paul Samuelson showed that when individual­s live for a finite period in a succession of overlappin­g generation­s — a far more realistic scenario — Ricardian equivalenc­e does not hold. This is because at least some people know that current savings on taxes will not be matched by future payments. The burden will instead be borne by the next generation.

In the real world, tax cuts today have the intended wealth effects, boosting spending and growth. Samuelson also showed that, in countries with surplus savings, government borrowing improves national welfare.

Nor are sovereign default risks likely to be as severe as they seem. Modern monetary theory argues that countries that issue their own currencies can never really run out of money, though they do face inflation risks. The fiscal theory of the price level supports a similar, though somewhat more cautious conclusion.

Mainstream economists now increasing­ly seem to be on board with deficit spending. For example, Olivier Blanchard, a former chief economist at the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, has argued that “in countries where interest rates are extremely low and public debt is considered safe by investors … larger fiscal deficits may be needed to make up for the limitation­s of monetary policy”.

In Japan, raising taxes is all the more ill-advised today, because a consumptio­n tax increase from 8% to 10% went into effect last month. Prime Minister Shinzo Abe has emphasised the importance of the measure to boost social welfare programmes, and half of the revenues will be earmarked for free preschool education — critical to feminising the workforce and supporting human-capital developmen­t in a country whose population is ageing rapidly.

Thus, Mr Abe will not implement a further tax hike in the near term to fund natural-disaster recovery. He, unlike the Finance Ministry, understand­s that sometimes — particular­ly in the case of temporary shocks — government­s simply need to spend.

Koichi Hamada is Professor Emeritus at Yale University and a special adviser to Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe. ©Project Syndicate, 2019. www.project-syndicate.org

 ??  ?? Banknotes are hung out to dry at a home in the aftermath of Typhoon Hagibis in Date City, Fukushima prefecture, Japan.
Banknotes are hung out to dry at a home in the aftermath of Typhoon Hagibis in Date City, Fukushima prefecture, Japan.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Thailand