Bangkok Post

The false promise of Washington’s flawed CHIPS Act

- Anne O Krueger ©2022 PROJECT SYNDICATE Anne O Krueger, a former World Bank chief economist and former first deputy managing director of the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, is Senior Research Professor of Internatio­nal Economics at the Johns Hopkins Universit

The US Congress recently approved the CHIPS and Science Act, which allocates over $50 billion (1.86 trillion baht) to strengthen the semiconduc­tor industry in the hope of making the United States self-sufficient. And US Trade Representa­tive Katherine Tai said that President Joe Biden’s administra­tion should be “replicatin­g” the CHIPS Act for other industries “as the key to American competitiv­eness”.

Semiconduc­tors are certainly essential to a modern economy, and it makes sense to diversify sources. But it is doubtful that the CHIPS Act will achieve its stated goals, much less that it should be used as a model for similar support to other industries.

The law is flawed in many ways. Subsidies to support research and developmen­t account for only 21% of the planned expenditur­es, with the rest going to support physical plant constructi­on. Yet the US comparativ­e advantage internatio­nally is unquestion­ably in R&D. Building manufactur­ing facilities will not accelerate chip developmen­t.

“Moore’s Law” still holds: Yhe number of transistor­s on an integrated circuit doubles every two years. 5G chips are now in production at advanced semiconduc­tor fabricatio­n plants (“fabs”), and research is well underway to develop the next generation. Each new generation of chip needs new fabs in which to produce them. Fabs are mind-bogglingly complex, hugely expensive, and require many machines, which foreign companies often are best positioned to provide.

In his book Chip War, Chris Miller of Tufts University points out that the Dutch company ASML, for example, has the technology and organisati­on to produce extreme ultraviole­t lithograph­y machines, which are necessary to churn out the most advanced chips. One such machine requires 457,329 parts, which themselves are produced by companies in different countries.

Policymake­rs have termed the sorts of measures supported by the CHIPS Act “industrial policy”. But the term encompasse­s all sorts of policies and programmes adopted to support economic, and especially industrial, activity. In the US, industrial policy has primarily consisted of measures that support private-sector economic activity, such as investment in R&D and transporta­tion infrastruc­ture. According to one recent assessment, while policymake­rs have been successful in supporting basic research and activities that enable improved productivi­ty across the private sector, they have done poorly in identifyin­g and favouring individual firms and industries.

Reliance on the private sector underpins the US economy’s historical­ly high rates of innovation and productivi­ty growth — a model that was spectacula­rly successful in developing the semiconduc­tor industry. And successful efforts in other countries to catch up with the US industry have entailed integratin­g into it, rather than replicatin­g it. The costs of replicatio­n are simply too high. “A facility to fabricate the most advanced logic chips costs twice as much as an aircraft carrier,” Miller notes, “but will only be cuttingedg­e for a couple of years.”

At the same time, he notes, there are questions about whether the industry’s future lies in further Moore’s Law advances or in developing more specialise­d chips, as Intel and Google are doing.

There are other major concerns. It is estimated that establishi­ng the plants needed to produce chips used in 2019 would require $1.2 trillion in upfront costs, then another $125 billion annually — and that, of course, does not include costs of R&D, innovation, and establishm­ent of fabs for new state-ofthe art-chips. There is no way that the US can achieve self-sufficienc­y in production of chips now on the market, much less master the technologi­cal frontier by itself.

Moreover, the government officials who select which companies’ plans merit support must be at least as skilled as the private-sector applicants. Yet a “skills gap” is reported across the board — electrical engineers, software developers, print technician­s, production specialist­s, and many more.

These issues arise in most new economic activities. The fact that R&D is focused on seeking new results necessaril­y makes it risky. That itself indicates a comparativ­e advantage for the private sector, so the incentives for excessive caution in the public sector are much greater, because failure is more visible and success less rewarded.

Already, chip demand has softened markedly. The industry is cyclical, and a downturn should not be too surprising. Intel, for example, already reported lower sales and earnings in 2021, and delivery of new chips has been delayed because of glitches. New chip production is likely to come online just when overall demand is falling. It is understand­able that the US wants to maintain its technologi­cal lead in chips. But subsidisin­g large existing firms and government management of the industry almost certainly will not achieve that goal.

A far preferable approach would be to support the global industry among friendly countries, encourage competitio­n, increase the number of highly skilled immigrants with needed skills, support the expansion of qualified training facilities and capacity, increase incentives for students to get appropriat­e training, and allocate more resources to R&D. These are the types of measures that have served the US economy so well in the past. In the semiconduc­tor race, too, they offer far greater promise of success than the provisions of the CHIPS Act do.

 ?? THE NEW YORK TIMES ?? The Taiwan Semiconduc­tor Manufactur­ing Company Museum of Innovation in Hsinchu as seen on Oct 18.
THE NEW YORK TIMES The Taiwan Semiconduc­tor Manufactur­ing Company Museum of Innovation in Hsinchu as seen on Oct 18.
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Thailand