Bangkok Post

US moves to bar noncompete clauses

FTC proposal expected to boost wages, increase competitio­n

- WASHINGTON (NYT)

In a far-reaching move that could raise wages and increase competitio­n among businesses, the Federal Trade Commission on Thursday unveiled a rule that would block companies from limiting their employees’ ability to work for a rival.

The proposed rule would ban provisions of labour contracts known as noncompete agreements, which prevent workers from leaving for a competitor or starting a competing business for months or years after their employment, often within a certain geographic area. The agreements have applied to workers as varied as sandwich-makers, hair stylists, doctors and software engineers.

Studies show that noncompete­s, which appear to directly affect roughly 20% to 45% of private-sector US workers, hold down pay because job switching is one of the more reliable ways of securing a raise. Many economists believe they help explain why pay for middle-income workers has stagnated in recent decades.

Other studies show that noncompete­s protect establishe­d companies from startups, reducing competitio­n within industries. The arrangemen­ts may also harm productivi­ty by making it hard for companies to hire workers who best fit their needs.

The FTC proposal is the latest in a series of aggressive and sometimes unorthodox moves to rein in the power of large companies under the agency’s chair, Lina Khan.

President Joe Biden hailed the proposal Thursday, saying that noncompete clauses “are designed simply to lower people’s wages.”

“These agreements block millions of retail workers, constructi­on workers and other working folks from taking a better job, getting better pay and benefits, in the same field,” he said at a Cabinet meeting.

The public will be allowed to submit comments on the proposal for 60 days, at which point the agency will move to make it final. An FTC document said the rule would take effect 180 days after the final version was published, but experts said it could face legal challenges.

The agency estimated that the rule could increase wages by nearly $300 billion a year across the economy. Evan Starr, an economist at the University of Maryland who has studied noncompete­s, said that was a plausible wage increase after their eliminatio­n. Starr said noncompete­s appeared to lower wages both for workers directly covered by them and for other workers, partly by making the hiring process more costly for employers, who must spend time figuring out whom they can hire and whom they can’t.

He pointed to research showing that wages tended to be higher in states that restrict noncompete­s. One study found that wages for newly hired tech workers in Hawaii increased by about 4% after the state banned noncompete­s for those workers. In Oregon, where new noncompete­s became unenforcea­ble for low-wage workers in 2008, the change appeared to raise the wages of

hourly workers 2% to 3%.

Although noncompete­s appear to be more common among more highly paid and more educated workers, many companies have used them for lowwage hourly workers and even interns.

About half of states significan­tly constrain the use of noncompete­s, and a small number have deemed them largely unenforcea­ble, including California.

But even in such states, companies often include noncompete­s in employment contracts, and many workers in these states report turning down job offers partly as a result of the provisions, suggesting that these state regulation­s

may have limited effects. Many workers in those states are not necessaril­y aware that the provisions are unenforcea­ble, experts say.

“Research shows that employers’ use of noncompete­s to restrict workers’ mobility significan­tly suppresses workers’ wages — even for those not subject to noncompete­s, or subject to noncompete­s that are unenforcea­ble under state law,” Elizabeth Wilkins, the director of the FTC’s office of policy planning, said in a statement.

The commission’s proposal appears to address this issue by requiring employers to withdraw existing noncompete­s and to inform workers that they no longer apply. The proposal would also make it illegal for an employer to enter into a noncompete with a worker or to try to do so, or to suggest that a worker is bound by a noncompete when he or she is not.

The proposal covers not just employees but independen­t contractor­s, interns, volunteers and other workers.

Defenders of noncompete­s argue that employees are free to turn down a job if they want to preserve their ability to join another company, or that they can bargain for higher pay in return for accepting the restrictio­n. Proponents also argue that noncompete­s make employers more likely to invest in training and to share sensitive informatio­n with workers, which they might withhold if they feared that a worker might quickly leave.

A ban “ignores the fact that, when appropriat­ely used, noncompete agreements are an important tool in fostering innovation,” Sean Heather, a senior vice president at the US Chamber of Commerce, said in a statement.

At least one study has found that greater enforcemen­t of noncompete­s leads to an increase in job creation by startups, though some of its conclusion­s are at odds with other research.

Starr said noncompete­s did appear to encourage businesses to invest more in training, but there was little evidence that most employees entered into them voluntaril­y or that they were able to bargain over them. One study found that only 10% of workers sought to bargain for concession­s in return for signing a noncompete. About one-third became aware of the noncompete only after accepting a job offer.

Michael R. Strain, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute, said that while there were good reasons to scale back noncompete­s for lower-wage workers, the rationale was less clear for better-paid workers with specialise­d knowledge or skills.

“If your job is to make minor tweaks to the formula for Coca-Cola, and you’re one of 25 people on Earth who knows the formula,” Strain said, speaking hypothetic­ally, “it makes total sense that Coca-Cola might say, ‘We don’t want you to go work for Pepsi.’”

He said that it might be possible to satisfy an employer’s concerns with a less blunt tool, like a nondisclos­ure agreement, but that the evidence for this was lacking.

In a video call with reporters Wednesday, Khan said she believed the FTC had clear authority to issue the rule, noting that federal law empowers the agency to prohibit “unfair methods of competitio­n.”

But Kristen Limarzi, a partner at Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher who previously served as a senior official in the antitrust division of the Justice Department, said she believed such a rule could be vulnerable to a legal challenge. Opponents would probably argue that the relevant federal statute is too vague to guide the agency in putting forth a rule banning noncompete­s, she said, and that the evidence the agency has on their effects is still too limited to support a rule.

 ?? ?? Lina Khan, head of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), speaks before a Senate Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transporta­tion in Washington, DC.
Lina Khan, head of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), speaks before a Senate Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transporta­tion in Washington, DC.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Thailand