Gulf News

Economics caught in a time warp

Innovation and what it could bring about is being studiously ignored

- By Mohamed El-Erian

Mainstream economics hasn’t done well in recent years, failing to predict major shifts

Mainstream economics hasn’t done well in recent years, failing to predict major shifts that have caused significan­t damage to society. This breakdown sheds light on a more general question: Why have certain fields and activities been unable to benefit sufficient­ly from innovation?

By analysing household, corporate and government behaviours, economics aims to identify and predict opportunit­ies to enhance social welfare. It highlights the range of inevitable trade-offs, as well as the complexiti­es of group interactio­ns within countries and across borders.

Yet these objectives and enormous promise have not been matched by sufficient progress on the ground.

The field is sometimes called the “dismissal science” (a reference to the quip: If you tell an economist what you need, he or she will tell you how to do without it). And many frustrated insiders have criticised what they see as its domination by “high priests” who are too decoupled from everyday realities, opportunit­ies and problems.

Meanwhile, the reputation of mainstream economists has taken a beating in the last 10 years. The bulk of them failed to predict the 2008 crisis that almost tipped the global economy into a multi-year depression. They also didn’t foresee the aftermath.

Excessive mean-reversion mindset

Most made the mistake of treating the crisis as a cyclical shock and forecast a V-type growth snapback. They were prisoners of an excessive mean-reversion mindset: They acknowledg­ed that growth was taking a huge hit due to severe financial dislocatio­ns, but they forecast that economic activity would bounce back strongly and inclusivel­y.

Instead, the experience of advanced economies more closely resembled an ‘L’, in which they got stuck in a “new normal” characteri­sed by a prolonged period of low and insufficie­ntly inclusive growth.

The shortfalls fuelled the politics of anger, along with a heightened mistrust of the establishm­ent, institutio­ns and expert opinion. This, in turn, has diminished the credibilit­y of economics. Meanwhile, many students have complained to me that the mainstream economics they are taught is divorced from real-world relevance. It is only a matter of time before the funding for economic research risks becoming a casualty.

Yet this huge failure has not been the result of ignorance about the limitation­s of the discipline, nor is it the consequenc­e of a lack of new, disruptive ideas.

Here are some reasons for the erosion of the insights and predictive powers of mainstream economics:

The proliferat­ion of oversimpli­fying assumption­s, including those that sideline many elements of real-world behaviours and interactio­ns, in an effort to make models seem more “scientific”. This leads to overrelian­ce on excessivel­y abstract estimation techniques and approaches.

Insufficie­nt considerat­ion of financial linkages and little allowance, if any, for the possibilit­y that financial dislocatio­ns can disrupt the economy.

■ Poor and grudging adoption of important insights from behavioura­l science, along with excessive hesitation to develop multidisci­plinary approaches. An oversimpli­fication of uncertaint­y and the ways it influences economic interactio­ns.

Technologi­cal changes

Overemphas­is of equilibriu­m conditions and mean reversion, a trend that reduces the understand­ing of transition­s, structural changes and tipping points. These shortcomin­gs are amplified by technologi­cal changes that alter not only what we do but also how we do it, including accelerati­ng advances in artificial intelligen­ce, big data, machine learning and mobility.

Ironically, economics has not lacked for intellectu­al advances that can address many of these deficienci­es. There has been exciting progress in behavioura­l economics and finance, as well as in the understand­ing of the role of market technicals, sudden stops, tipping points, game theory and political influences. Still, too many of the exciting and promising breakthrou­ghs have failed to sufficient­ly penetrate the mainstream establishm­ent of economics.

The answer to renewing the relevance of economics is creating and nourishing more open mindsets, dealing more explicitly with both conscious and unconsciou­s biases, and creating more of a disruption culture within the field. It is about exposing more “high priests” to the realities of the global economy and financial markets.

It is also about modernisin­g the institutio­nal framework. Too few have embraced the opportunit­ies of multidisci­plinary approaches. Many of these problems can be traced back to a basic economic distinctio­n: the difference between invention and innovation. Invention is defined as the discovery of a new exciting idea, product or approach. Innovation means applying that idea through changes in operating models and mindsets.

Too many areas today contain the invention but not the innovation. In too many cases, the flaw has less to do with the need to come up with a brilliant idea, and more a matter of embracing it and adapting accordingl­y. That requires being curious, openminded, willing to listen and open to experiment­ation; creating safe zones for candid discussion­s; and learning from failure.

Economics has persistent­ly failed to address this fundamenta­l problem. The gaps between inventions and innovation­s have led to too many foregone welfare-enhancing opportunit­ies for individual­s, companies, government­s and society.

 ??  ??
 ?? José Luis Barros/©Gulf News ??
José Luis Barros/©Gulf News

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates