Khaleej Times

In China, corporates are also the party’s business

Hypercontr­ol, interventi­onism, currency manipulati­on — no, China is not a market economy

- Yi-Zheng Lian

There, they said it: China is not a market economy.

In December, 15 years after China’s accession to the World Trade Organizati­on, the European Union, the United States and Japan formally refused to grant Beijing the coveted label, denying it important concession­s on tariffs and other trade restrictio­ns.

This is partly a response to economic distortion­s caused by government interventi­on, including an excess supply of steel, which China exports and dumps in advanced industrial­ised countries, harming local producers and workers. China’s many high-profile moves to open up its markets in recent years turn out to have been halfhearte­d, if not intentiona­l hoodwinkin­g.

Despite the much-ballyhooed dismantlin­g of the more than 2,000-yearold state monopoly on salt, all salt producers are still state-owned. Foreign asset-management companies are now allowed to operate wholly foreignown­ed businesses in China, but only in deals with institutio­nal investors and private-equity funds, not retail investors. Partly to steady the renminbi, Beijing no longer allows Chinese citizens to take up to $50,000 a year out of the country, and it has recently restricted the repatriati­on of capital by foreign firms like Deutsche Bank.

Hypercontr­ol, interventi­onism, currency manipulati­on — no, China is not a market economy. But it’s worse than that: The Chinese Communist Party (CCP) has systematic­ally infiltrate­d China’s expanding private sector and now operates inside more than half of all non-state firms; it can manipulate or even control these companies, especially bigger ones, and some foreign ones, too. The modern Chinese economy is a party-corporate conglomera­te.

It all began in 1927. The idea was to instil a fighting spirit throughout the ranks by ensuring the party’s top commands would be relayed all the way down. Party branches were set up at the company level, party cells at the platoon and squad levels, and together they recruited foot soldiers who were solid party material. In a few years, an unruly peasant army was whipped into a formidable fighting force. The rest is history.

Fast-forward to 2002 and the CCP’s 16th national congress, convened under Jiang Zemin. In the interval, China underwent two revolution­s. The first, in 1949, establishe­d a communist state; the second, in 1978, jettisoned a stagnant socialist planned economy in favour of pro-market reforms. By 2002, China was competing with France to be the world’s fifth-largest economy, and the Chinese people’s entreprene­urial spirit had been reawakened. Much of the political elite, including relatives of party and government officials, had become the owners and managers of private businesses.

To legitimise the growing importance of these so-called new social strata, the party congress inducted many of their influentia­l members into the CCP. The move would have been heresy under canonical Marxism, but it was made acceptable by the convenient adoption of a new ideology: socialism with Chinese characteri­stics. It was also an astute bargain. In return for becoming politicall­y acceptable, capitalist­s and top business managers at private firms would come under the party’s chain of command.

The year before the party started controllin­g the managerial classes, it had already begun to manipulate how private companies ran their businesses. Starting in 2001, every private sector firm with at least three CCP members among its employees was required to have a party unit. Much like the party cells in the Red Army decades earlier, party units in companies were expected to “firmly implement the Party’s line, principles and policies,” as the constituti­on of the CCP stipulates.

This control mechanism had been a fixture of state-owned enterprise­s since the first days of the communist republic. It was brought into the private sector in earnest in 2001 — just on the heels of China’s accession to the WTO — and extended after the 2002 party congress. Around 2006, it was introduced to private firms set up with foreign capital, like Wal-Mart. Official figures for 2015 show that nearly 52 per cent of all nonstate firms had party cells in-house. Such cells are now also common in foreign companies, and even foreign nongovernm­ental organisati­ons, at least among bigger, more establishe­d ones.

This should greatly worry foreign businesses and foreign government­s because the constituti­on of the CCP requires all members to “adhere to the principle that the interests of the party and the people stand above everything else, subordinat­ing their personal interests to the interests of the party.”

Consider the implicatio­ns. For example, a foreign firm employs a Chinese senior manager, giving him access to its proprietar­y technology; he is also a member of the CCP and the firm’s party unit. One day his party superior orders him to transfer a trade secret from the firm to a local rival. In the name of party and country, he can only comply.

The problem isn’t just that the Chinese economy isn’t a market economy. Its very structure, including in the private sector, has been designed — and is redesigned, again and again — to serve the CCP’s will and its interests, economic and political. This party-corporate complex is only going to expand as most state-owned enterprise­s, inefficien­t holdovers, are being supplanted by the fast-growing private sector.

Yi-Zheng Lian is a commentato­r on Hong Kong and Asian affairs. —The NYT Syndicate

The very structure, including in the private sector, has been designed and redesigned to serve the CCP’s will and its interests, economic and political

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates