The National - News

A beginners’ guide to candidates for this year’s Nobel Prize for economics

- CASS SUNSTEIN Comment Cass Sunstein is a Bloomberg View columnist. He is the author of #Republic: Divided Democracy in the Age of Social Media

Because economics is such a diverse field, with many distinguis­hed thinkers, predicting the winner of the Nobel Prize in economics is notoriousl­y difficult. But suppose that we narrowed the field, so as to focus on candidates who have not only made important theoretica­l contributi­ons, but have also had a significan­t impact on the world, and affected the lives of numerous people?

If that is the standard, here are some leading contenders for the prize, which is to be announced today:

Esther Duflo, Massachuse­tts Institute of Technology.

Government­s are keenly interested in the actual effects of their interventi­ons, but they often lack tools to establish what works and what doesn’t. Building on work in medicine and related fields, Ms Duflo has pioneered the use of randomised controlled trials. One group of people serve as a control; another group, otherwise identical, is subjected to a policy interventi­on, designed to reduce disease, increase access to loans, reduce poverty or improve education. If the trials are done properly, they can be used isolate the actual effects of the interventi­on. That is huge progress.

In recent work, Ms Duflo argues that an economist can be a plumber: “She installs the machine in the real world, carefully watches what happens, and then tinkers as needed.” Focusing on poverty and developmen­t, Ms Duflo’s trials are providing invaluable informatio­n to policymake­rs and getting help to many people who need it.

Richard Posner, University of Chicago. Recently retired from the federal bench, Mr Posner is the leading thinker behind the field of law and economics, which tries to analyse legal rules with the help of economic tools.

Suppose that a local government imposes a rent control law, or that a state court strikes down certain contracts as “unconscion­able” because they are unfair to poor people. What are the likely effects? Whether the issue involves occupation­al safety, automobile accidents, antitrust law, consumer protection or the role of private property, public officials, lawyers and judges are now using the methods that Mr Posner helped introduce.

William Nordhaus, Yale University.

The problem of climate change raises unusually difficult problems for economists, not least because of high levels of uncertaint­y about the likely effects, tough questions about how to turn those effects into monetary equivalent­s, and serious challenges, at the intersecti­on of economics and philosophy, about how to deal with harm to future generation­s.

More than anyone else, Mr Nordhaus has produced discipline­d, rigorous and luminously clear thinking about all of these questions, in a way that is transparen­t about underlying assumption­s and that makes real progress on, and possibly even solves, some seemingly intractabl­e problems.

His work played a defining role in the efforts of the US to produce a “social cost of carbon”, which in turn influenced many regulatory initiative­s.

W Kip Viscusi, Vanderbilt University. Mr Viscusi is rarely listed among Nobel candidates, but his work on the monetary valuation of risks to life and health has had a massive effect. In the US alone, it plays a major role in the work of the environmen­tal protection agency, the department of transporta­tion, the department of energy, the department of labour and the department of health and human services.

These agencies and many others build on Mr Viscusi’s work on the “value of a statistica­l life.” He does not really ask what a life is worth; he is interested in the value of statistica­l risks. If, for example, workers face a mortality risk of 1 in

100,000, how much compensati­on do they get in return? Suppose that the best answer is in the vicinity of US$90. With a little multiplica­tion, that produces a $9 million value for a statistica­l life – roughly Mr Viscusi’s own figure, which is, not coincident­ally, the value now used by most agencies of the US government.

Richard H Thaler, University of Chicago.

Over recent decades, the rise of behavioura­l economics has been the most interestin­g developmen­t in economic theory. More than anyone else, Mr Thaler has been responsibl­e for that developmen­t.

He has shown that in concrete ways, people do not act as predicted by standard economic theory. Far from seeing money as fungible, people put their cash in separate “mental accounts” (mortgage money, vacation money, retirement money). Investors overreact to unexpected news events. Human beings care about fairness -- and they are willing to pay something to punish people who have been unfair. People are planners as well as doers, and when they are planning, they might try to foil their own doing.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates