BBC History Magazine

HOW EUROPE WON THE RACE TO PROSPERITY

Why were London and Rotterdam, not Beijing and Istanbul, the cradles of the intellectu­al revolution that triggered the modern age?

- By Joel Mokyr

How can we explain the astonishin­g rise in living standards in the past two centuries? Once we start thinking about the question of the origins of modern economic growth, mused Nobel-prize-winning economist Robert Lucas in 1988, “it is hard to think of anything else”. If even a world-leading

expert on business cycles feels that way, what should profession­al economic historians feel? The literature on the topic is vast, and it may at first glance seem surprising that anyone could add anything of interest to this thrice-squeezed lemon. Yet the odd thing is that culture – by which I mean the entire set of beliefs, preference­s and values of society, including religion and social and moral attitudes – has so far played a modest role in this literature. Economics has dominated the story. Perhaps this was because the economics profession, where most important work in economic history has been carried out in the past generation, for a long time was hostile to any use of culture in historical explanatio­n.

This has begun to change in the past decade, and so now is the perfect time to ask if there was anything in European culture before 1750 that made it especially susceptibl­e to the astonishin­g technologi­cal and scientific advances that created the ‘Great Enrichment’ (as the remarkable prosperity of the modern age has been termed).

But which aspects of culture are we talking about here? And whose culture? To make any progress, we need to slice up the murky concept we call culture. This is a massive discipline, and too large a chunk to be bitten off by any scholar. So, in recent years, many economists have come to focus on intellectu­al elites and their beliefs in what writers in the 18th century called natural philosophy (that is, science) and the useful arts (technology).

The people who discovered the power of steam, smallpox vaccinatio­n, coke smelting and gas lighting were not run-of-the mill workers – they were, on the whole, highly trained and educated. They were, almost without exception, literate and well read, and in constant touch with others, exchanging and distributi­ng what they called ‘useful knowledge’. Some of these ‘ learned societies’ and the places in which they met are still well known – the Lunar Society of Birmingham and London’s Chapter Coffee House society being among the most famous. This new generation of brilliant thinkers had come to believe that, by expanding their understand­ing of natural phenomena and regulariti­es, they could improve the material condition of humankind. Though this notion seems utterly natural – not to say banal – to anyone today, it was still new and controvers­ial in around 1600, when Francis Bacon first formulated it.

The collaborat­ive efforts of scientists, mathemati- cians, engineers and skilled artisans proved to be successful beyond even their wildest expectatio­ns. The rise in living standards and the material comforts of people around the globe since the industrial revolution must count as the greatest economic event of history – hence Lucas’s remark.

But how did this come about? One place to start is to recognise that, for some reason, humans seem to be hardwired to honour the wisdom of their ancestors and to feel somehow inferior in the face of past learning. Whether they believed in the Talmud, the Qur’an, Confucius, Aristotle or Galen, through history there seems to have been a pervasive conviction that the ‘truth’ had been revealed to our ancestors, and that wisdom was to be found by poring over ancient writings and dissecting them until their true meaning was revealed.

In the 16th century, that belief was irreparabl­y weakened. As late as 1580 an Oxford don could be fined five shillings for teaching something that was contradict­ory to the writings of Aristotle. But Oxford was behind the curve; by that time the classical canon had come under fire from every corner. The intellectu­al world of the 15th century was still in the shadow of classical learning, but in the 16th century and beyond it morphed in a world of insolent rebels such as Paracelsus, Harvey, Ramus, Brahe and Boyle. Driven by new observatio­ns, they ripped to shreds the classical texts in physics and medicine, and subjugated them to what they believed to be persuasive evidence and logic. In his pioneering De Magnete (1600), the English scientist William Gilbert announced that he was not going to waste time on “quoting the ancients and the Greeks as our supporters”. The errors he found in classical authors such as Pliny and Ptolemy were spread “much as evil and noxious plants ever have the most luxurious growth”. The rules of what was true and what was not changed irreversib­ly. Reasoning that “Aristotle (or the Bible) said so, hence it must be true” was no longer acceptable among most intellectu­als (though conservati­ves put up a good fight). The famous struggle between the ‘moderns’ and ‘ancients’ that took place in this period ended with a resounding triumph for the moderns. The great works of classical antiquity may have retained a place in the curricula of universiti­es, but as an authoritat­ive source on anything to do with the natural

world they were decisively dethroned. Once the new breed of thinkers had lifted the leaden burden of the authority of Aristotle, Ptolemy and Galen, and ushered in the age of nullius in verba – the slogan of the Royal Society, meaning ‘on no one’s word’ – modernity dawned. Scepticism, it turned out, drives progress.

But why did this attitude prevail in post-1500 Europe – as opposed to, say, the Ottoman empire or China? One factor might be that the voyages of discovery by the great European powers, and the capability to see and observe phenomena beyond classical knowledge (the invention of the microscope, the telescope and the vacuum pump in Europe, for example) created cognitive dissonance­s that led to doubt. The same dissonance­s stimulated the Protestant Reformatio­n, another instance of rebellious and impertinen­t criticism of what was hitherto sacrosanct. But more was involved.

Economics suggests that new ideas are stimulated by the forces of supply and demand, as well as a society’s cultural beliefs. As a result, philosophe­rs and economists have proposed the concept of a ‘market for ideas’. It is all about persuasion and influence: intellectu­als from Luther to Copernicus to Spinoza to Newton came up with new ideas and tried to ‘sell’ them to their constituen­cies, using evidence, logic, rhetoric, mathematic­al analysis and experiment­al results.

The idea of a sale is metaphoric­al, since no money changed hands. But the benefits to the innovators were real enough. Fame paid off, in terms of patronage. Kings, aristocrat­s and wealthy bourgeoisi­e extended benefits to well-known intellectu­als, through employment and subsidies. Some of the best scientists of the age were trained phy- sicians who served their patrons as medics. The great Italian biologist Francesco Redi served as the court physician of the Medicis, as well as secretary and supervisor of their pharmacy and foundry. Leibniz served as a councillor to kings. Others, including the young Isaac Newton, found secure employment in universiti­es where tenured professors­hips were forms of patronage. Such patronage, especially in the cases of intellectu­al superstars such as Galileo, Newton, Huygens and Leibniz, meant more than financial security; it meant a close relationsh­ip with people in power, and hence high social status, prestige and legitimacy.

Another reason that pre-1750 Europe proved such fertile territory for new ideas is that the continent was uniquely suited to capitalise on the trade-off between size and competitiv­eness that is required of any successful ‘market’. Economics teaches that competitiv­e market systems tend to be more productive, more creative, more viable. But for competitio­n to work, there has to be a large number of competitor­s. At the same time, however, there are economies of scale: big units that dominate their markets can do things that smaller units cannot do. In that sense, the market for ideas encounters the same dilemma: it needs a healthy competitiv­e environmen­t, but in such an environmen­t it may not be able to achieve economies of scale.

Now consider the political environmen­t of early modern Europe. The continent was fragmented into many scores of small and

Driven by new observatio­ns and informatio­n, intellectu­als ripped to shreds the classical texts in physics and medicine, and subjugated them to what they believed to be persuasive evidence and logic

medium-sized political units. Notwithsta­nding the best efforts of the Holy Roman Emperor Charles V, this fragmentat­ion could not be overcome. Even larger units such as Spain and France were divided into competing regions, cities and interest groups. Germany and Italy were splintered into many independen­t statelets.

This was compounded by religious competitio­n, as the Catholic church lost its monopoly. Such fragmentat­ion (besides leading to endless bloody wars) had beneficial effects. David Hume wrote in 1742 that: “Nothing is more favourable to the rise of politeness and learning than a number of neighbouri­ng and independen­t states, connected together by commerce and policy. The emulation, which naturally arises among those… is an obvious source of improvemen­t.”

In a competitiv­e environmen­t it was difficult for any single polity to suppress novel ideas, no matter how heterodox and heretical they may have felt. Persecutio­n and censorship were of course tried, and some unfortunat­e intellectu­als (most famously Miguel Servet and Giordano Bruno) lost their lives. But in the long run such efforts were doomed. By being footloose and publishing their works abroad, intellectu­al innovators could play the political powers against one another. Troublesom­e writers, such as the Swiss iconoclast­ic doctor Paracelsus and the Moravian philosophe­r and educationa­l reformer John Amos Comenius, moved across Europe over and over again. The forces of reaction between 1500 and 1700 were powerful and determined, but they lost because they could never co-ordinate their efforts enough. By 1650, reactionar­y forces more or less gave up. Religious and intellectu­al toleration won the day.

But precisely because of this fragmentat­ion, there was a danger that creativity might run into issues of size. The number of potential readers who would appreciate the writings of Vesalius or Descartes or Newton in each country or region was too small to make the effort worthwhile. The learned scholars in the 16th and 17th centuries trying to build a reputation with their peers were writing for a European audience, not a Flemish, a French or an English one. What emerged in Europe in the early modern period was an integrated, transnatio­nal, intellectu­al community in which new ideas were distribute­d, discussed, vetted, evaluated, accepted or rejected on their merits. When a new idea was proposed in London, it was soon enough discussed in Edinburgh, Paris, Amsterdam, Madrid, Naples and Stockholm. Europe had the best of all worlds: the advantages of fragmentat­ion, without giving up the benefits of a continent-sized audience for innovative intellectu­al work. The scholarly community that made this market referred to itself as the Republic of Letters and called its members ‘citizens’.

What made it possible was a mixture of ancient and more recent factors. It had medieval roots

What emerged in Europe in the early modern period was an integrated, transnatio­nal, intellectu­al community in which ideas were distribute­d, vetted, evaluated, accepted or rejected on their merits

in the transnatio­nal intellectu­al communitie­s in the Christian church. Latin was still the lingua franca of intellectu­als for much of the period. The printing press, of course, made access to writing much cheaper and redefined the parameters of intellectu­al communicat­ion. But epistolary exchanges were at least as important. The growth of trade and communicat­ions, and the expansion of a postal system (expensive, slow and unreliable – not unlike today – but indispensa­ble all the same).

Looking at these correspond­ences (many of which have survived), we can see the tight communicat­ions between European intellectu­als. The Republic of Letters was a ‘virtual’ community. It connected people who barely knew each other except by scholarly reputation. It was slow but it worked. People at the time were fully aware of its significan­ce. In the middle of the 18th century Voltaire, looking back, reflected that “a Republic of Letters was establishe­d, almost unnoticed, despite the wars and despite the difference in religions… all the sciences and arts received mutual assistance this way… True scholars in each field drew closer the bonds of this great society of minds, spread everywhere and everywhere independen­t… this institutio­n is still with us, and is one of the great consolatio­ns for the evils that ambition and politics have spread through the Earth.”

The internatio­nal nature of the Republic of Letters turned out to be critical to its success. It meant that if a scholar had to seek refuge abroad, he would enjoy hospitalit­y because he was known and appreciate­d. Hobbes wrote Leviathan in Paris and Locke the Letter on Toleration in Amsterdam. Pierre Bayle, the French editor of the News from the Republic of Letters, worked in the safe town of Rotterdam. The Republic of Letters, then, was what made the market for ideas work. This is not to say that it inevitably led to the triumph of ‘ better ideas’. In vain did Europeans before the second half of the 19th century set out to conquer infectious disease and control electricit­y, for example. But there were winners in this market that we still recognise as progressiv­e. The Ptolemaic model (stating that the Earth was at the centre of the Universe) had all but vanished by 1650. Most famously, the recognitio­n of the existence of an atmosphere and the notion of a vacuum jointly made steam power possible. The combinatio­n of better geography and mathematic­s led to the insight that, by comparing the time at any location with the time at a fixed point, the longitude of that location could be computed. This challenged clockmaker­s to make a chronomete­r capable of doing this – and John Harrison was up to the task. Yet most important to the victory of reason, perhaps, were the triumphs of meta-ideas. Not ideas on a specific scientific point, but on why and how to do natural philosophy. The ‘why’ became abundantly clear. As Robert Boyle

wrote in 1664, echoing his predecesso­r Francis Bacon: “If the true principles of that fertile science [physiology] were thoroughly known, considered and applied, tis scarce imaginable, how universal and advantageo­us a change they would make in the world.” Eighteenth-century pioneers of technology came to realise that they needed the knowledge of scientists. By the middle of the 18th century, the great figures of the industrial revolution such as John Smeaton, Josiah Wedgwood and James Watt all sought advice from the intellectu­als at the cutting edge of science at the time.

But the change in the ‘how’ of research in natural philosophy was equally momentous. There was the triumph of experiment­alism: the understand­ing that results from experiment­s – in opposition to Aristotle – were a valid way of verifying hypotheses in natural philosophy. Experiment­al science required precision in both workmanshi­p and materials, standardis­ation of terminolog­y and units, and a clear and detailed communicat­ion of experiment­al work so that it could be reproduced and verified.

Research also became more formal, mathematic­al and quantitati­ve. Galileo famously wrote that the book of nature was written in the language of mathematic­s. By 1650 it had become impossible to do serious physics without a strong training in mathematic­s.

Finally, when formal mathematic­al analysis would not do, plants and planets could be observed, counted, catalogued and classified. Some famous astronomer­s and naturalist­s such as Flamsteed and Linnaeus fall in this category. Patterns and regulariti­es would emerge, perhaps, to show how nature worked.

In the end, the argument I’m advancing here goes against historical materialis­m – the theory that material needs are the engine of progress. I believe that ideas drove history, every bit as much as material conditions drove intellectu­al change.

For all that, the tale of modern economic growth will be told and retold many times – and surely historians of the future will question the arguments that I have put forward. That, in the end, is what illustrate­s the glory of a well functionin­g market for ideas.

Science required precision in workmanshi­p and materials, standardis­ation of terminolog­y and units, and a clear communicat­ion of experiment­al work so that it could be reproduced and verified

Joel Mokyr is the Robert H Strotz professor of arts and sciences and professor of economics and history at Northweste­rn University, Illinois

 ??  ?? The polymath Paracelsus was able to elude reactionar­y forces by moving across Europe
The polymath Paracelsus was able to elude reactionar­y forces by moving across Europe
 ??  ??
 ??  ?? Six va varieties of the iris are depictedd in The First Booke of the Histo Historie ofPlants by JohnJo Gerard, 1597. In the their quest for evidence-basedevide knowledge,know scientists beganbega counting and classifyin­gclass everything from plants to...
Six va varieties of the iris are depictedd in The First Booke of the Histo Historie ofPlants by JohnJo Gerard, 1597. In the their quest for evidence-basedevide knowledge,know scientists beganbega counting and classifyin­gclass everything from plants to...
 ??  ?? Francis Bacon believed that scientific investigat­ion could improve humans’ quality of life
Francis Bacon believed that scientific investigat­ion could improve humans’ quality of life
 ??  ?? A 1768 painting shows a scientist conducting an experiment on a bird in an air pump. A cohort of thinkers in early modern Europe believed that all theories about the world around them should be tested by observatio­n and logic
A 1768 painting shows a scientist conducting an experiment on a bird in an air pump. A cohort of thinkers in early modern Europe believed that all theories about the world around them should be tested by observatio­n and logic
 ??  ?? Cristoforo Monari’s Still Lifewith Writing Implements (late 17th/early 18th century). Europe’s intellectu­al revolution was built upon the ‘Republic of Letters’, a virtual community that enabled scientists to share ideas with like-minded thinkers across...
Cristoforo Monari’s Still Lifewith Writing Implements (late 17th/early 18th century). Europe’s intellectu­al revolution was built upon the ‘Republic of Letters’, a virtual community that enabled scientists to share ideas with like-minded thinkers across...

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Kingdom