The Daily Telegraph

Scrap OBR and Bank of England independen­ce

Threadneed­le Street’s purpose should be to support economic growth, not to make forecasts

- DAVID DAVIS David Davis is the Conservati­ve MP for Haltempric­e and Howden and a former Cabinet minister

As I listened to the Chancellor present the Budget last week, I thought that he did a very elegant job of coping with a very difficult global backdrop, although I would have much preferred significan­tly greater tax cuts – at least 2p off income tax over and above his employee National Insurance cuts, for example. But he was clearly boxed in by a seriously dysfunctio­nal policy architectu­re.

It is perfectly understand­able that Jeremy Hunt is cautious of unnerving the markets in the aftermath of Liz Truss’s disastrous mini-budget.

The problem is that the OBR forecasts, swallowed by the markets as unerringly authoritat­ive, turn this handicap into a set of policy shackles.

The trouble is that the OBR’S forecasts are alarmingly inaccurate. In 2022 the OBR’S UK borrowing forecast was over £100bn off the mark.

A report on the OBR by the Conservati­ve Way Forward campaign group has recently suggested that, since 2010, the combined total of the OBR’S errors in growth forecasts aggregates to a figure of over £500bn, and the OBR’S errors in forecastin­g public sector net borrowing accumulate to over £600bn.

When the Treasury talks about headroom, it is based on the fiscal rule that requires national debt to decline as a proportion of GDP in 2029. In effect, it is basing our economic strategy on the difference between two guesses about what will happen at the end of the next five years – guesses that have historical­ly not been proven correct. You could see this in action as newspapers in the last few months reported “headroom” figures shrinking from £30bn to around £9bn for no obvious reason, dramatical­ly limiting the options available to the Chancellor.

In addition to the previous error margins, the simple fact is that these forecasts are incredibly sensitive to tiny changes in assumption­s. You can pick a range of sensible assumption­s which will none the less give massive discrepanc­ies in outcomes.

In practice, each forecast carries a different suite of risks. The Chancellor ought to be able to choose which assumption­s he wants to input and, in essence, which risks he wants to take on and which policy aims he wants to adopt.

Further exacerbati­ng this issue is the fact that the OBR and Bank of England themselves work off different assumption­s and forecasts. Not only have their forecasts been wrong, but they are wrong in distinct ways. What sort of organisati­on can operate on two separate and entirely incompatib­le sets of assumption­s? If a listed company ran its production arm off one set of assumption­s and its marketing arm off another, shareholde­rs would rightly revolt. If I had my way, I would input assumption­s encouragin­g more demand, increased productivi­ty and growth, rather than the ones that could lead us into an austerity spiral with low growth for several years – which appears to be the Bank of England’s preferred approach.

It is not just the Bank’s forecastin­g that distorts our economic policy, it is its very mission. The UK (and the rest of Europe) has pitiful growth rates compared to the US. A major contributo­ry reason for this is that the requiremen­ts of the Federal Reserve Board, the US central bank, do not orbit solely around targeting inflation at 2pc at the cost of all else, as the Bank of England’s do. It must take on board growth objectives as well in its policy generation. It is not even as though the Bank of England has been successful in reaching this limited aim, with forecasts failing to predict the worst inflation crisis in generation­s.

The origins of the Bank’s independen­ce are, in fact, political, not economic. This independen­ce was granted in 1997; done in large part to mitigate fears of an incoming Labour government acting financiall­y irresponsi­bly.

While it was very successful in that regard, there is no indication that its decisions have been any better since then than before Labour came into power. Margaret Thatcher and Nigel Lawson made better decisions than every government since the independen­ce of the Bank was establishe­d.

The OBR, in conjunctio­n with the Bank of England, effectivel­y hems in our government, making it impossible for the economy to escape the debt trap it faces owing to the everincrea­sing cost of servicing its current debt. The only solution is to dramatical­ly boost productivi­ty.

Paradoxica­lly that might involve some short-term deficit financing.

The only way to do this is by increasing public investment to ensure businesses have the environmen­t and infrastruc­ture to thrive.

The Bank of England’s purpose should be rebalanced to support economic growth. We should go back to the period in our history when forecaster­s were greeted with healthy scepticism rather than a final sign-off on the direction of our government’s economic policy.

Nigel Lawson famously disbelieve­d all forecasts. Today there is a strong argument that the institutio­nal structure of our decision-making is flawed, and it is time to finesse and, in some cases, abandon these rules.

We should abolish the OBR, bring the Bank within the Government’s policy framework, and liberate the Chancellor to deliver the best policies he can for Britain.

‘It is not even as though the Bank of England has been successful in reaching its limited aim’

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Kingdom