The Independent

Government securities are a headache for investors

- SATYAJIT DAS

Government securities were once regarded as gilt-edged investment­s, guaranteei­ng a steady income and safety of capital. Income levels have declined with lower rates. No more!

Heavily indebted government­s have seen their credit standing decline, making return of principal less certain. Even where the state can print money to meet its liabilitie­s, the purchasing power of investors in government bonds may be eroded. Trade and currency wars mean that internatio­nal investors face additional risks.

National Front leader Marine Le Pen has indicated that if she gains France’s presidency euro denominate­d government bonds will be re-denominate­d in new French Francs.

The risks are compounded by the fact that the entire global financial system is now underpinne­d by the use of government bonds as collateral to secure financial transactio­ns. The practice continues to be a central

tenet of banking regulation, despite its role in compoundin­g the 2008 crisis.

Collateral is used to secure borrowing, structured as repurchase­d agreements as well as mortgages over or pledges of real estate or other assets. In derivative transactio­ns, collateral is lodged periodical­ly to secure current mark-to-market exposure.

But there are several issues with collateral. As Yogi Berra astutely observed, “in theory there is no difference between theory and practice. In practice there is”. Rather than make the financial system safer, collateral use does not reduce but creates different risks.

First, the emphasis shifts from the borrower or counterpar­ty’s creditwort­hiness to the collateral. Focus on financial strength and ability to perform is reduced. Parties normally ineligible to borrow or transact in the first place are able to enter into transactio­ns. The rapid growth in debt levels, volume of derivative contracts and hedge funds or structured investment vehicles relies on collateral.

Second, the choice of collateral, originally limited to cash and government securities, creates risks. Even government securities now are not risk free.

To accommodat­e growth, the range of securities accepted as collateral has increased. In these cases, the value attributed to each security is adjusted by “haircuts”, introducin­g the risk of volatile unexpected changes in the value of the collateral itself.

The correlatio­n between the risk covered and the value of the collateral becomes crucial. Wrong way correlatio­n, where the underlying risk increases at the same time the value of the collateral decreases, reduces its utility as security.

Third, it assumes liquid markets for the collateral, which must be realised in case of default. Fourth, it creates asset liability mismatches where the loan is for a shorter maturity than the security pledged or where collateral must be adjusted frequently over the life of the transactio­n. Unexpected changes in the amount of collateral needed create liquidity risks.

Fifth, collateral use entails significan­t model risk. The underlying exposure (in the case of derivative­s) as well as the value of the collateral must be determined. As evident during crises, there are difficulti­es in valuing less liquid securities, as well as risk of potential manipulati­on of and disputes about valuations. Models must establish the level of initial collateral posted, to cover the fall in value between the last margin call and the close out date. Initial margin amounts are based on historical volatility that may be inadequate in periods of stress. Where collateral is calculated on a portfolio basis, offset methodolog­ies (based on correlatio­n) may be flawed.

Sixth, collateral introduces significan­t operationa­l and legal risk. It places large demands on operationa­l procedures to ensure mark-to-market calculatio­ns are accurate, collateral is paid and received, collateral is monitored and control over the cash or securities are held. The legal validity of these arrangemen­ts in all jurisdicti­ons is not assured because of a complex mix of domestic and internatio­nal laws. Enforcemen­t may be practicall­y difficult because of the frequent unwillingn­ess of courts to enforce foreign judgements.

Seventh, the use of collateral entails moral hazards. While lowering collateral levels increases leverage but decreases risk mitigation, pressure to increase business volumes may lead to inadequate collateral­isation.

Finally, collateral has systemic risks which deeply alter the functionin­g of financial markets, especially the quantum of credit available, liquidity risk and behaviour.

Use of collateral is an important source of endogenous liquidity. The practice of re-hypothecat­ion – where collateral received is re-pledged to support other transactio­ns – allows exponentia­l expansion in leverage. But if re-hypothecat­ion is restricted, then the cash and securities committed as collateral cannot be used, precipitat­ing a rapid contractio­n in liquidity.

Reliance on collateral encourages the creation of high quality securities that lenders are willing to lend against. This led to the creation of complex structured securities, reliant on complex ratings models. According to the Bank for Internatio­nal Settlement­s, between 1990 and 2006, AAA rated securities increased from around 20 per cent to over 55 per cent of all securities on issue, with asset-backed securities accounting for about two-thirds of the increase.

Collateral exacerbate­s financial distress risk where a solvent party cannot meet unexpected margin calls. Limited disclosure of collateral provisions and potential liquidity claims also makes it difficult to assess the financial position of counterpar­ties.

Where collateral use is widespread, it exacerbate­s the problem of herding behaviour. In periods of stress, market participan­ts all seek more collateral or need to sell pledged securities increasing market instabilit­y, potentiall­y fatally.

Collateral use is becoming more entrenched. Banks rely on secured funding, including repos with central banks. Regulation­s encourage the use of collateral through favourable capital treatment. The Central Counter Party (CCP), the key element of derivative market reform, is predicated on collateral­isation.

Economist Hyman Minsky identified three phases of finance. Hedge financing is where income flows can meet principal and interest on debt used to finance. Speculativ­e financing is where income flows cover only interest repayments but not principal, requiring debt to be continuall­y refinanced. Ponzi finance is where income flows cover neither principal nor interest repayments with the borrower relying on increasing asset values to service debt.

In the progressio­n from hedge financing to Ponzi finance, asset prices become completely delinked from fundamenta­l values until the structure collapses as no one is willing to borrow or lend the required amounts to finance asset purchases. The decline in quality of once gilt edged government securities and their inappropri­ate use of collateral is central to this process.

Satyajit Das is a former banker. His latest book is ‘A Banquet of Consequenc­es’ (published in North America as ‘The Age of Stagnation’ to avoid confusion as a cookbook). He is also the author of ‘Extreme Money’ and ‘Traders, Guns & Money’

 ??  ?? Collateral use is becoming more entrenched as banks rely on secured funding (Getty)
Collateral use is becoming more entrenched as banks rely on secured funding (Getty)

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Kingdom