Antelope Valley Press

Don’t overlook minimum wage’s negative effects

- Veronique de Rugy Veronique de Rugy is a senior research fellow at the Mercatus Center at George Mason University.

In his autobiogra­phy, “Up From the Projects,” the late economist Walter Williams explained his move away from the belief that minimum wages help the poor.

His change of heart on the topic began when one of his UCLA professors asked him whether he cared more about the intentions behind the minimum wage or its effects.

Williams devoted much of his profession­al career to studying minimum wages and documentin­g their negative effects, particular­ly on young Black people. While Williams had the good sense to learn that good intentions alone are insufficie­nt to produce good public policy, many others have failed to learn this lesson.

The latest illustrati­on is an attempt to jack up the minimum wage to $15 per hour as part of another COVID-19 relief bill. Rep. Ro Khanna, D-Calif., recently declared on CNN’s “Inside Politics” that small businesses wouldn’t struggle under a federal mandate to pay employees $15 an hour, even during a recession.

To support his claim, he pointed out that Target and Amazon, two of the greatest beneficiar­ies of the lock-down, raised their lowest hourly wage to $15 voluntaril­y. He later asserted that he doesn’t want small businesses that are underpayin­g workers and that $15 is very reasonable. How he knows this is a mystery, but this arrogance demonstrat­es an ignorance of basic economics.

Walter Williams summarized the general position of economists on this issue in an article titled “Minimum Wage, Maximum Follies.”

He wrote, “While there is a debate over the magnitude of the effects, the weight of research by academic scholars points to the conclusion that unemployme­nt for some population groups is directly related to legal minimum wages. The unemployme­nt effects of the minimum-wage law are felt disproport­ionately by non-whites.”

Minimum wages reduce the employment of low-skilled workers — a group disproport­ionately represente­d by immigrants, inner-city minorities and young people. Some workers lose jobs altogether, while others see their hours reduced. This doesn’t mean that there are no beneficiar­ies of higher minimum wages. Economic theory predicts that some workers who are currently employed will retain their jobs with no reduction in hours, even after the minimum wage is increased. For those workers, the increase means higher take-home pay, although the jobs themselves might become more demanding or less secure.

So, what do we know about raising the federal minimum wage to $15, even gradually? In theory, we know a lot, but the empirical evidence is limited since so few states and localities have tried it. There are, however, some noteworthy attempts to get a good grasp of what might happen.

First, the Congressio­nal Budget Office estimates that a $15 minimum wage by 2025 would eliminate 1.4 million jobs over that period. The CBO also forecasts that this increase could decrease business income, increase consumer prices and tap the brakes on the economy.

Second, economists at the University of Washington studied the employment effects of Seattle’s move to gradually increase its minimum wage to $15. Seattle, already a high-wage city, first raised its minimum wage to $13 in 2016 and hiked it to $15 in 2021.

Summing up the findings in Seattle, Michael Strain writes in Bloomberg: “The economists found that this led to a 9% reduction in low-wage jobs. The pay increase it generated didn’t make up for the reduction in employment, and earnings fell for low-wage workers overall. The economists’ subsequent research found that the gains from the higher minimum wage accrued to more experience­d workers.”

As I noted, there are some winners (those who are already relatively better) and some losers (those already worse off).

In a recent Twitter thread, one of the authors of the study, Jake Vigdor, noted that the following pattern emerges for employers dealing with higher labor costs: “1) Don’t lay people off 2) Cut back hours 3) Cut back hiring 4) As workers quit, restore hours for those who remain.”

He also warns that the negative employment effects are somewhat understate­d in the study because it ignores “a subset of the workforce: those who didn’t have jobs at baseline, before the wage increase.”

Workers who didn’t have a job at the time of the increase and won’t get one after may pay the steepest (and unseen or overlooked) cost of the minimum wage. As Williams explained in his autobiogra­phy, “Early work experience­s not only provide the pride and self-confidence that comes from financial semi-independen­ce but also teach youngsters attitudes and habits that will make them more valuable and successful workers in the future.”

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States