Arkansas Democrat-Gazette

The high price of health-care deductible­s

- MEGAN MCARDLE

Recently in the New York Times, reporter Robert Pear wrote about the high deductible­s of the exchange policies that most people are buying. While some things, such as birth control and an annual wellness visit, must be covered, effectivel­y these are catastroph­ic policies that require people to spend a considerab­le amount of money out of pocket before the coverage kicks in. This has come as quite a shock to many; as one person told Pear, “When they said affordable, I thought they really meant affordable.” Which it is, if you don’t get sick.

This is actually good insurance design. Insurance that covers routine expenses isn’t really insurance; it’s a sort of inefficien­tly expensive prepayment plan. If President Obama’s health-care law forces people away from “first dollar” coverage with low or no deductible and toward plans that cover people only for unanticipa­ted emergencie­s, that would be a win for economic logic.

The problem with this is twofold: First, unless they’re pegged to income, high deductible­s are regressive, forcing the poorest people to pay the largest share of their income. And second, people absolutely hate economical­ly logical health-care plans. This is why you see unions giving up quite a lot of other concession­s on wages and benefits in order to keep those goldplated health-care plans.

The regressive­ness of the deductible­s is mitigated by Obamacare’s cost-sharing reduction subsidies, which limit your deductible­s if you make less than 250 percent of the federal poverty line (about $60,000 for a family of four). But those subsidies are available only on Silver plans, which carry higher premiums. And economical­ly strapped families often have trouble spending more money now to save money later.

Regardless of subsidies, the political problem remains: Insurance on the exchanges is quite expensive considerin­g how high the deductible­s are and how limited the provider networks are. That’s making people unhappy, and seems likely to generate political pressure to make the policies more generous, which is to say, more expensive. It’s also a market problem.

Over the past five years, healthcare wonks have started to see health insurance less as a way to ensure health and more as a way to avoid financial disaster. (As one health-care economist told me, the results of the Oregon Medicaid Study, which raised questions about how much insurance really improves health, aren’t that surprising; insurance is a financial product, and what it does really well is give people financial protection.) The alternativ­e to buying health insurance may not be dying young; it may be bankruptcy, or at least a trashed credit report after you’ve negotiated settlement­s on all your medical bills.

That substantia­lly changes the calculatio­n people make when they decide to buy insurance. Bankruptcy is terrible. But you’d probably pay a lot less for bankruptcy insurance than you would for insurance that made you healthier. Especially if high deductible­s mean you’re going to face a trashed credit report either way. This may, in fact, be the calculatio­n that people were making before Obamacare passed, and may explain why uptake has been slow among people who don’t qualify for large subsidies.

Republican­s are eager to capitalize on discontent with deductible­s. But the high deductible­s and narrow networks are not some strange artifact of Obamacare’s design; yes, the coverage mandates have made the policies more expensive than they used to be for a given level of deductible, but mostly they cost a lot because health insurance is quite expensive. There are only really three ways to reduce insurance premiums: cover less, pay lower prices for what you cover, or force consumers to pick up a bigger share of the costs. The government doesn’t want plans to cover less; it wants them to cover more. So the first is out. The second is why Obamacare plans have smaller networks—a result of paying lower prices to providers, many of whom then choose not to accept the insurance. The third way is also pronounced “higher deductible­s and copays.”

Yes, you liberal in the back, I see you waving your hand. You would like to tell me that there is a fourth way: The government could “use its bargaining power” to “negotiate down costs,” effectivel­y price controls. (“Bulk buying” is not why Canada pays lower prices for things than Aetna, which covers about a third more people than our neighbor to the north.) Theoretica­lly the government could do this. A lot of other government­s do. But it’s a lot harder than you think. European government­s have largely held down prices by not letting them grow so fast. That is a much different political operation from suddenly slashing the income of all the people in the healthcare system.

Because that’s where the money is going in the end: to people. And not just to greedy health-care executives. Or to rapacious pharmaceut­ical firms, whose products constitute just 9.3 percent of total health-care spending in America, much of it on off-patent generics rather than pricey brand-name drugs. With the exception of pharma, which is more like the tech industry than a health-care business, profit margins at insurers and hospital groups are surprising­ly modest. Vast oceans of money flow in, yes, but almost all of it flows right back out in the form of payments for wages, facilities and supplies.

A recurring theme of discussion­s of health-care reform is the desire to believe that there are a small number of villainous cretins out there who are siphoning off large percentage­s of the trillions we spend on health care each year. All we have to do, this suggests, is hold those villains upside down and shake them until all our money falls back out of their pockets. If only. The health-care sector is one of the few remaining that offers stable, well-paid jobs at all levels, from doctors down to LPNs. If you want to hold healthcare costs, you’re going to have to grab all of their ankles and shake hard. And they are apt to scream about it. Which is why no member of Congress has really dared to try.

It’s not Obamacare’s fault that it didn’t manage to do the impossible: provide cheap, nearly comprehens­ive health-care coverage without ballooning the deficit. No other reform could have done it either without tackling provider prices. And no politicall­y feasible reform could have tackled provider prices because America’s 12 million health-care workers would have been marching on Washington with pitchforks, or at least running tear-jerking ads to great popular effect. To paraphrase G.K. Chesterton, the idea of providing more generous coverage by cracking down on provider prices has not so much been tried and found wanting as found difficult and left untried, by both conservati­ves and liberals.

You can’t really blame Obamacare for the fact that the most affordable insurance offers rather scanty coverage for the average user. But you can blame the law’s architects for over-promising. They should have been more honest with themselves and with voters about the limits of what they could actually do. But if they had been, the law probably would never have passed.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States