Arkansas Democrat-Gazette

Dangers of Sado-Monetarism

- Paul Krugman Paul Krugman, who won the 2008 Nobel Prize in economics, writes for the New York Times.

Sado-monetarism is having a moment. And one of the biggest risks now facing the U.S. economy is that it will have too much influence over policy.

This term was coined by William Keegan to describe Margaret Thatcher’s economic policies. But sado-monetarist has come to mean a person who always seems to demand higher interest rates and fiscal austerity, regardless of the state of the economy.

Such people have had a good year: The inflation they’ve always warned about finally materializ­ed. In 2021, U.S. policymake­rs, like many economists, myself included, badly underestim­ated inflation risks, as they admit. This candor, incidental­ly, is refreshing and welcome. Back in the 2010s, very few of those who wrongly predicted runaway inflation ever admitted having been wrong.

More important, policymake­rs are acting to undo their mistakes. Budget deficits are plunging. The Federal Reserve has begun raising the interest rates it controls, and the longer-term rates that matter for the real economy—especially mortgage rates and corporate borrowing costs—have soared. These policies pretty much ensure a slowdown in the U.S. economy, which might be sharp enough to be considered a mild recession.

But there’s a loud chorus of voices insisting that the Fed must tighten even more—that it must drive the U.S. economy into a sustained period of high unemployme­nt something like the big slump of the early 1980s. And there’s a real danger that the Fed may be bullied into over-reacting.

So let’s talk about why the demands for even more aggressive Fed action are misguided.

How did inflation get so high? A large part of the story involves shocks like rising oil and food prices, disrupted supply chains and so on that are outside the control of policymake­rs—that is, policymake­rs other than Vladimir Putin, whose invasion of Ukraine has seriously damaged the world economy.

These nonpolicy shocks explain why inflation has soared almost everywhere; British inflation just clocked in at 9.1 percent.

And the breadth of inflation suggests that the combinatio­n of large federal spending last year and easy money has caused the economy to overheat—that we’ve been suffering from a classic case of too much money chasing too few goods.

Policymake­rs have already taken strong steps to cool the economy down. Why isn’t that enough?

The answer I keep hearing is that harsh policy is necessary to restore the Fed’s credibilit­y. And to be fair, there are good reasons to believe that credibilit­y is an important factor in keeping inflation under control. What we don’t have are good reasons to believe that this credibilit­y has been lost.

Economists have long accepted the idea that persistent inflation can be self-perpetuati­ng. By 1980, for example, almost everyone expected high inflation to continue indefinite­ly—and these expectatio­ns were reflected, among other things, in big wage deals that gave inflation a lot of inertia. So Paul Volcker, the Fed chairman at the time, had to impose a severe extended slump to break the inflationa­ry cycle.

But aside from the sado-monetarist­s, who currently expects inflation to remain persistent­ly high (as opposed to staying high for, say, the next year)?

Not the financial markets. On Wednesday, the five-year break-even inflation rate—a measure derived from the spread between U.S. government bonds that are and that aren’t protected against inflation—was 2.74 percent. Part of that reflects expectatio­ns of near-term price rises that investors don’t expect to continue; the markets expect inflation to fade.

What about the general public? Last month, economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which carries out regular surveys of consumer expectatio­ns, noted that consumers apparently expected inflation to “fade over the next few years” and that five-year expectatio­ns had been “remarkably stable.”

A few weeks ago a different survey, from the University of Michigan, showed a bump in longterm inflation expectatio­ns, which had previously been stable. But the New York Fed numbers didn’t show the same bump. As anyone who works with economic data can tell you, you shouldn’t make too much of one month’s number.

I’m not saying that any of these prediction­s are necessaril­y right. What they tell us, instead, is that expectatio­ns of persistent inflation aren’t entrenched the way they were in 1980. So it doesn’t look as if we need harsh Volcker-type policies that punish the economy until morale improves.

Inflation is a real problem, and tighten the Fed must. But it will be tragic if the Fed listens to people who are in effect demanding a much deeper slump than the economy seems to need.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States