Austin American-Statesman

Robots and robber barons trim workers’ slice of pie

- From the left Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Krugman writes forthe New York Times. Friday Saturday Sunday

The

American economy is still, by most measures, deeply depressed. But corporate profits are at a record high. How is that possible? It’s simple: Profits have surged as a share of national income, while wages and other labor compensati­on are down. The pie isn’t growing the way it should — but capital is doing fine by grabbing an ever-larger slice, at labor’s expense.

Wait — are we really back to talking about capital versus labor? Isn’t that an old-fashioned, almost Marxist sort of discussion, out of date in our modern informatio­n economy? Well, that’s what many people thought; for the past generation discussion­s of inequality have focused overwhelmi­ngly not on capital versus labor but on distributi­onal issues between workers, either on the gap between more- and lesseducat­ed workers or on the soaring incomes of a handful of superstars in finance and other fields. But that may be yesterday’s story.

More specifical­ly, while it’s true that the finance guys are still making out like bandits — in part because, as we now know, some of them actually are bandits — the wage gap between workers with a college education and those without, which grew a lot in the 1980s and early 1990s, hasn’t changed much since then. Indeed, recent college graduates had stagnant incomes even before the financial crisis struck. Increasing­ly, profits have been rising at the expense of workers in general, including workers with the skills that were supposed to lead to success.

Why is this happening? As best as I can tell, there are two plausible explanatio­ns. One is that technology has taken a turn that places labor at a disadvanta­ge; the other is that we’re looking at the effects of a sharp increase in monopoly power. Think of these two stories as emphasizin­g robots on one side, robber barons on the other.

About the robots: There’s no question that in some high-profile industries, technology is displacing workers of all, or almost all, kinds. For example, one of the reasons some high-technology manufactur­ing has lately been moving back to the United States is that these days the most valuable piece of a computer, the motherboar­d, is basically made by robots, so cheap Asian labor is no longer a reason to produce them abroad.

In a recent book, “Race Against the Machine,” MIT’s Erik Brynjolfss­on and Andrew McAfee argue that similar stories are playing out in many fields,

Scot Lehigh

Paul Krugman

Dana Milbank

Maureen Dowd including services like translatio­n and legal research. What’s striking about their examples is that many of the jobs being displaced are high-skill and highwage; the downside of technology isn’t limited to menial workers.

Still, can innovation and progress really hurt large numbers of workers, maybe even workers in general? I often encounter assertions that this can’t happen. But the truth is that it can, and serious economists have been aware of this for almost two centuries. The early 19th century economist David Ricardo is best known for the theory of comparativ­e advantage, which makes the case for free trade; but the same 1817 book in which he presented that theory also included a chapter on how the new, capital-intensive technologi­es of the Industrial Revolution could actually make workers worse off, at least for a while — which modern scholarshi­p suggests may indeed have happened for several decades.

What about robber barons? We don’t talk much about monopoly power these days; antitrust enforcemen­t largely collapsed during the Reagan years and has never really recovered. Yet Barry Lynn and Phillip Longman of the New America Foundation argue, persuasive­ly in my view, that increasing business concentrat­ion could be an important factor in stagnating demand for labor, as corporatio­ns use their growing monopoly power to raise prices without passing the gains on to their employees.

I don’t know how much of the devaluatio­n of labor either technology or monopoly explains, in part because there has been so little discussion of what’s going on. I think it’s fair to say that the shift of income from labor to capital has not yet made it into our national discourse.

Yet that shift is happening. For example, there is a big, lavishly financed push to reduce corporate tax rates; is this really what we want to be doing at a time when profits are surging at workers’ expense? Or what about the push to reduce or eliminate inheritanc­e taxes; if we’re moving back to a world in which financial capital, not skill or education, determines income, do we really want to make it even easier to inherit wealth?

As I said, this is a discussion that has barely begun — but it’s time to get started, before the robots and the robber barons turn our society into something unrecogniz­able.

Gail Collins

John Young

Leonard Pitts

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States