Austin American-Statesman

Why Fed’s rate debate is both overblown, ominous

- Ramesh Ponnuru He is a columnist for Bloomberg View and is a senior editor at the National Review. Ponnuru is a Bloomberg View columnist and a senior editor for National Review; rponnuru@bloomberg.net.

Contrary to many people’s expectatio­ns, the Federal Reserve refrained last month from raising the interest rate over which it has fairly direct control. That means we can expect several more months of debate over whether the world will end if the Fed raises rates too soon — or if it waits too long.

There are two odd things about this debate. The first is that proponents of an interest rate increase generally treat it as an end in itself. The second is that a tiny increase in the federal funds rate should be thought to be so important either way.

Typically, the central bank raises interest rates to tame inflation. But the inflation rate has run below the Fed’s 2 percent target for years, and market expectatio­ns suggest it will remain low for years to come. So the line is that the Fed should raise rates because they’ve been unnaturall­y low for too long, and it’s time to “normalize” them.

The assumption is that the Fed has intervened in the market by maintainin­g a “zero-interest rate policy” and that the Fed should now retreat to a more modest role. Raising rates would help savers who have been punished with low returns for years. Sometimes it is added that artificial­ly low rates have inflated asset bubbles.

Ben Bernanke, the former Fed chairman, has explained why these assumption­s are mistaken. The main reason interest rates have been so low since the financial crisis of 2008 isn’t because the Fed is holding them low, but because the “natural” or “equilibriu­m” interest rate has been lower still thanks to the weakness of the economy. Trying to raise interest rates, Bernanke argues, would have been just as much of an interventi­on as keeping them low. Hiking rates prematurel­y would have hurt the economy, forcing the Fed to engage in more stimulativ­e policies.

Many people think that low interest rates are a sign of loose monetary policy. Bernanke’s points raise the possibilit­y that the Fed hasn’t been nearly as accommodat­ive as most people think. Perhaps — although he doesn’t draw this conclusion — it has even been too tight.

Either way, you might wonder why markets have gotten so worked up over every hint from the Fed about what it plans to do. The main action under considerat­ion, after all, is a mere quarter-point increase in the federal funds rate. Is our economy really so fragile that such a modest change would be disruptive?

The Fed doesn’t follow a simple rule in setting its policies. It is deliberate­ly opaque. That puts a premium on evidence of its true goals.

Raising the federal funds rate 25 basis points with the inflation rate so low would be powerful evidence about the general mindset at the Fed — about how worried its members are that they’ve been too accommodat­ive, about how they weigh the risks of tightening, about their willingnes­s to hold rates low for years after a future crisis. Tightening policy would signal that future policy will also be tighter, compared with a world where the Fed declines to raise rates.

It would also mean that the Fed thinks the key question for monetary policy now is, “When do we finally get to raise interest rates?” It’s not irrational for markets to worry about that.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States