Baltimore Sun

The congressio­nal districts we want

- By Michael Towle Michael Towle (towle@msmary.edu) is a professor of political science at Mount Saint Mary's University.

Once the U.S. Supreme Court issues its gerrymande­ring decisions, we will be barraged with claims about what this means for the political parties. Before the inevitable jump to partisan interpreta­tions, it might make sense to reflect first on the types of districts that Americans would want to see.

Consider an election with two hypothetic­al districts.

The first district has been drawn in such a way as to protect one political party, and the incumbent is always re-elected with over 65 percent of the vote, often without any credible challenger­s. This type of district is frequently seen in a state with a clearly dominant party — like Maryland, which packs its minority party voters into a few districts — or in states with divided government­s where the parties come up with mutually beneficial compromise maps.

The second district has been gerrymande­red as part of a plan by one party — perhaps the minority party among the state’s voters — to give itself a disproport­ionate advantage by creating many districts with a 55 percent to 45 percent outcome, while packing the other party’s voters into fewer districts with overwhelmi­ng majorities. This is what happened in Pennsylva- nia after Democratic losses in the 2010 elections resulted in unified Republican control just in time for the new census and redistrict­ing plan. (That map was struck down earlier this year by the Pennsylvan­ia Supreme Court for violating the state’s laws and constituti­on, and will result in new maps for the November elections.) Which situation is worse? In the first district, two-thirds of the voters are happy with the outcome of the election. But their member of Congress has no need to moderate her views to attract more centrists, and can go to Washington without any need to seek compromise with the other party.

In the second district, a much higher percentage of the district’s voters is unhappy with the outcome of the election. On the other hand, this district might actually change hands when there is a shift in voter sentiment, thus forcing the representa­tive to attempt to find ways to appease some of his constituen­ts.

There are competing values at stake. There is the value of having overall election outcomes that are proportion­al to statewide voter sentiment. There is the value of maximizing the number of voters who are happy with their elected representa­tive. And there is the value of electing people who have some motivation to temper their partisan impulses and reach across the aisle.

Unfortunat­ely, the Supreme Court’s decision will not resolve this underlying conflict. The court might be able to resolve some of the questions of proportion­ality, but as long as we draw lines to elect one representa­tive per district, the process of drawing lines will be a choice between larger numbers of dissatisfi­ed voters, or districts with representa­tives who have no need to curb their partisan impulses.

Most democracie­s try to lessen the effects of these conflictin­g values through election systems that either: increase the number of representa­tives from each district, create proportion­al outcomes or require run-off elections to force a minimum threshold of support and interparty compromise­s.

But these systems also tend to result in multiple political parties. It is generally accepted among political scientists that the election method used in the United States to elect the House tends to result in two dominant political parties. For all their partisan squabbling, the one thing that Democrats and Republican­s would agree upon is that there should only be two parties. And as long as they have a hold on our government system, we are unlikely to escape from this.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States