Daily News (Los Angeles)

Revisit Prop. 13 to help unleash our economy

- By Thomas Irwin Thomas Irwin works for a nonprofit in Los Angeles focused on economic developmen­t.

For the last 50 years, rightof-center politics in California has been laser-focused on one subject: keeping taxes low. For these voters, the passage of Propositio­n 13 in 1978 was a monumental achievemen­t that put hard caps on how much property taxes could rise for existing homeowners. Even as California politics has become dominated by Democrats, Prop. 13 has become considered an untouchabl­e part of California politics. This is a real problem because Prop. 13 has eroded economic opportunit­y in California, and it’s high time we take action to reform the outdated law.

The merits of Prop. 13 are often argued along the lines of political beliefs in the size of government. Progressiv­es in California bemoan the forgone revenue, and conservati­ves embrace Prop. 13 as a means of “starving the beast” and constraini­ng the size of government. But this debate is tired and inaccurate to facts on the ground: Studies show that tax and expenditur­e limits like

Prop. 13 are generally ineffectiv­e at limiting spending. California is no exception: In 1978, California had the fourth-highest tax burden of any state in the nation. In 2022, California has the fifth-highest burden in the country. Why is this? California has adapted to Prop. 13 by increasing other taxes, collecting the fourth-highest personal income tax, the seventh-highest corporate income tax, the highest state sales tax, and the seventh-highest combined sales tax. Prop. 13 hasn’t kept taxes from rising; it’s shifted the tax burden to alternativ­e taxes.

Worse yet, Prop. 13 has perverse impacts on good taxation policy. The Tax Foundation’s tax policy principles include simplicity and neutrality. Unfortunat­ely, Prop. 13 violates both principles through one of its central features: It bars the re-assessment of a home’s value unless it is sold or re-developed. This provision has led to huge disparitie­s in tax burdens, as many homes in California have doubled or tripled in value over the last 10 years. As someone who is house hunting, I get angry when I look at tax records and realize I will have to pay five to 10 times the tax rate of my neighbors simply because I happened to buy into the market decades later.

Let’s imagine that tomorrow, California proposes that half the residents would pay a 20% tax on their income, while half would pay a 2% tax on their income, decided by a coin flip. That would be unfair. But this is precisely the system that Prop. 13 sets up — two identical properties can be taxed at wildly diverged rates based solely on the luck of when you were able to buy into the market. In 2018, the Los Angeles Times found that actor Jeff Bridges and his siblings paid $5,700 in property taxes on the Malibu mansion they inherited, which was estimated to be worth $6.8 million in 2018. The paper estimated that at a theoretica­lly identical house next door, a new purchaser would be paying at least $76,000 annually in property taxes, a rate 13 times greater than the Bridges.

Voters who believe in the importance of economic growth should embrace property taxes as the best way for government­s to raise the revenue they need. All taxation hinders economic growth to some extent, but property taxation does far less to deter growth when compared to income or sales taxes. Since land cannot leave the state, many across the political spectrum have argued that land-focused taxation can create economic growth by encouragin­g property owners to respond to market incentives to develop their land, maximizing its market value. Milton Friedman famously called land taxes the “least bad tax,” while conservati­ve urban planning guru Chuck Marohn argues that land value taxes can incentiviz­e economic growth in under-invested communitie­s.

Unfortunat­ely, Prop. 13 flips this incentive around. Because redevelopm­ent and improvemen­ts can trigger a property tax reassessme­nt, property owners are encouraged to do nothing and become land speculator­s, free-riding off rising prices throughout California. Worse yet, after Prop. 13, California nudged cities to charge developer fees as an alternativ­e source of revenue. Today, some cities’ fees are over $150,000 per unit, which drives up housing prices and discourage­s developmen­t. This combinatio­n of perverse incentives has encouraged California’s cities to become simultaneo­usly stagnant and outrageous­ly expensive, as valuable land with great economic potential sits underutili­zed.

A full-scale repeal of Prop. 13 would be politicall­y untenable and highly disruptive, but that does not preclude all reform. One idea would be to eliminate Prop. 13’s prohibitio­n on the re-assessment of property values for all future property transactio­ns (both sales and inheritanc­es) while allowing existing homeowners to keep their current assessment while they stay in their homes. In addition, reform could give commercial and investment properties a short grace period (i.e., five years) before reassessme­nts begin. While this would allow tax inequities in the short-run, these would phase out over time without creating disruption­s for those who bought their home under the assumption­s of Prop. 13. Finally, assessment reform could be partnered with imposing strict limits on municipal developer fees to ensure that the tax burden on new buyers is limited.

The second idea would be to reform Prop. 13 to create a split-rate system, where the tax rate on improvemen­ts is limited or even eliminated, but the tax rate on land is allowed to rise (on eligible properties). Evidence from split-rate taxes in Pennsylvan­ia showed that most homeowners would not see land taxes increase their taxes, especially in less affluent areas of California where land prices are low.

Housing policy is California’s most concrete barrier to economic growth. As the crisis worsens, the state Legislatur­e has started to address zoning reforms, albeit far too slowly. Partnering these zoning changes with property tax incentives that promote, not penalize, building housing could unleash growth. Of course, no housing reform will fix all of California’s economic problems, but Prop. 13 reform is still a necessary step in the right direction.

 ?? TIM BOYLE — GETTY IMAGES ?? Should new buyers really pay 13times as much in property taxes as inheritors?
TIM BOYLE — GETTY IMAGES Should new buyers really pay 13times as much in property taxes as inheritors?

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States