Dayton Daily News

Trump’s tariffs have clear winner, mostly unseen loser

- Walter E. Williams He writes for Creators Syndicate.

There are a couple of important economic lessons that the American people should learn. I’m going to title one “the seen and unseen” and the other “narrow well-defined large benefits versus widely dispersed small costs.” These lessons are applicable to a wide range of government behavior, but let’s look at just two examples.

Last week, President Donald Trump enacted high tariffs on imports of steel and aluminum. Why in the world would the U.S. steel and aluminum industries press the president to levy heavy tariffs? The answer is simple. Reducing the amount of steel and aluminum that hit our shores enables American producers to charge higher prices. Thus, U.S. steel and aluminum producers will earn higher profits, hire more workers and pay them higher wages. They are the visible beneficiar­ies.

But when the government creates a benefit for one American, it is a virtual guarantee that it will come at the expense of another American — an unseen victim. The victims are the companies that use steel and aluminum. Faced with higher input costs, they become less competitiv­e on the world market. For example, companies such as John Deere may respond to higher steel prices by purchasing their parts in the internatio­nal market rather than the U.S. To become more competitiv­e in the world market, some firms may move their production facilities to foreign countries that do not have tariffs on foreign steel and aluminum. Studies by both the Peterson Institute for Internatio­nal Economics and the Consuming Industries Trade Action Coalition show that steel-using industries — such as the U.S. auto industry, its suppliers and manufactur­ers of heavy constructi­on equipment — were harmed by tariffs on steel enacted by George W. Bush.

Politician­s love having seen beneficiar­ies and unseen victims. In the cases of the steel and aluminum industries, company executives will know whom to give political campaign contributi­ons. Workers in those industries will know for whom to cast their votes. The people in the steel- and aluminum-using industries may not know whom to blame for declining profits, lack of competitiv­eness and job loss.

Then there’s the phenomenon of narrow well-defined large benefits versus widely dispersed small costs. A good example can be found in the sugar industry. Sugar producers lobby Congress to place restrictio­ns on the importatio­n of foreign sugar through tariffs and quotas. Those restrictio­ns force Americans to pay up to three times the world price for sugar. A report by the U.S. Government Accountabi­lity Office estimated that Americans pay an extra $2 billion a year because of sugar tariffs and quotas. Plus, taxpayers will be forced to pay more than $2 billion over the next 10 years to buy and store excess sugar produced because of higher prices. Another way to look at the cost side is that tens of millions of American families are forced to pay a little bit more, maybe $20, for the sugar we use every year.

Even if the people knew what the politician­s are doing, it wouldn’t be worth the cost of trying to unseat a legislator whose vote cost them $20 a year. Politician­s know that they won’t bear a cost from sugar consumers. But they would pay a political cost from the sugar industry if they didn’t vote for tariffs. So they put it to consumers — but what else is new?

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States