Inland Valley Daily Bulletin

Immigratio­n enriches nations and humanity

- Veronique de Rugy Columnist Veronique de Rugy is a senior research fellow at the Mercatus Center at George Mason University.

Exactly 10 years ago, economist Michael Clemens published a paper in the prestigiou­s Journal of Economic Perspectiv­es called “Economics and Emigration: Trillion-Dollar Bills on the Sidewalk?”

He urged fellow economists to consider a paradigm shift in their research about immigratio­n. Though economists had mostly neglected the global economic losses caused by migration barriers, the existing estimates “should make economists’ jaws hit their desks.”

As a fellow at a Washington, D.C., anti-poverty think tank called the Center for Global Developmen­t, Clemens suspected this research would reveal that by restrictin­g immigratio­n, the amount of wealth we leave on the table globally is in the trillions of dollars.

He notes it’s essential to seek a better characteri­zation of the gains to labor mobility globally — gains for the countries to which migrants go and for the countries they leave. He highlighte­d a few issues economists should explore, including “the magnitude and mechanisms of the effect of workers’ location on their productivi­ty, relative to the effect of workers’ inherent traits on their productivi­ty.”

In layperson terms: How much does where you live matter to your productivi­ty?

Thankfully, many economists answered Clemens’ call. In fact, it’s hard to overstate the importance of this paper and the impact it has had on this field of research.

As George Mason University economist and renowned immigratio­n scholar Bryan Caplan wrote to me, “Before Clemens’ seminal paper, even immigratio­n’s biggest fans failed to understand the strongest argument for their own position. Namely: Virtually everyone, regardless of skill, is much more productive in the First World than the Third World.” And that doesn’t just apply to high-skilled immigrants. It also applies to very low-skilled immigrants, who, when they immigrate, can tap into labor markets with efficientl­y run firms, predictabl­e legal systems and ample capital

Market vendor Kerline Joseph arranges her fruit in Petionvill­e, Haiti. While it’s almost impossible for Third World farmers to prosper, research shows that when they emigrate to richer nations, they thrive in the same way tech workers do.

(think of a tractor instead of a wooden hoe or an electric saw rather than an ax).

In his illustrate­d book, “Open Borders: The Science and Ethics of Immigratio­n,” Caplan asks, “how productive would you be in Haiti?” The answer is not very. Better yet, we now know that immigrants aren’t the only beneficiar­ies of their relocation­s. Caplan explains: “(Immigrants become) so much more productive, in fact, that open borders turn out to be the world’s greatest policy opportunit­y for humanity. Trapping human talent in poverty isn’t just terrible for would-be migrants; it is also terrible for everyone who would have enjoyed consuming all the wealth that wouldbe migrants could have produced.”

Here’s one of the ways immigrants benefit all of us: A farmer who stays in his relatively poorer country contribute­s virtually nothing to the global economy. Yet that changes once he arrives in a country where he produces so much more food that a lot of it

can be sold on export markets. The global food supply rises, benefiting all people who eat, including Americans. After all, more supply means lower food prices everywhere.

In addition, more immigratio­n means a deeper market for housing, making home sales easier when you wish to move. More immigratio­n also increases the ease of finding caregivers for children, nurses for aging parents and landscaper­s for lawns — all of which improve prospects for others to pursue more lucrative employment. Parents, for example, can work longer and more certain hours, and the American who would otherwise mow lawns can become owner or manager of a lawncare company.

More immigratio­n also increases the constructi­on of offices, retail space and housing. And yes, while immigratio­n may lower local wages by increasing the supply of workers, immigratio­n also increases the number of consumers for other goods and services, which then increases wages by raising the

demand for more jobs. Which of these effects win? That’s one of the questions Clemens asked economists to tackle.

So far, the answer is that large-scale immigratio­n hasn’t made locals worse off economical­ly precisely for the reasons spelled out above. Growing evidence confirms what sound economic theory predicts: Barriers to immigratio­n make us all worse off.

There’s so much more to say about this issue. But I’ll conclude by saying that those who worry about the cultural or political risks of welcoming newcomers shouldn’t ignore the trillions of dollars of wealth we reject when we reject immigrants. It’s natural for immigratio­n skeptics to consider proposals that ensure immigrants earn the right to receive government welfare, but it’s not OK to leave enormous wealth untapped because of unwarrante­d fears.

 ?? DIEU NALIO CHERY — THE ASSOCIATED PRESS ??
DIEU NALIO CHERY — THE ASSOCIATED PRESS
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States