Las Vegas Review-Journal (Sunday)

Productivi­ty and the welfare state

- Robert Samuelson

Alan Greenspan, the former chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, weighed in recently on one of the pressing issues facing the Trump administra­tion and the country — slow economic growth. Greenspan’s explanatio­n is novel and is bound to be controvers­ial. To preview: He blames the welfare state and overall uncertaint­y for the slowdown.

Why should we listen to Greenspan? After all, wasn’t he the guy who brought us the 2008-09 financial crisis? Well, no. Granted, he made huge errors, but so did many others.

If Greenspan had become a profession­al musician, the financial crisis would still have occurred. And despite the crisis, Greenspan remains a highly original economic thinker.

“As an observer, analyst and forecaster, he was formidable,” writes Sebastian Mallaby, author of a critical but fair-minded biography of Greenspan. “He understood the interactio­ns between [financial] markets and the real economy better than most of his contempora­ries.”

Economic growth matters greatly. Faster growth raises people’s incomes, while also increasing government’s tax revenues. Unfortunat­ely, as is well known, growth has disappoint­ed. Since 2010, it’s averaged about 2 percent annually, significan­tly below the 3 percent average since World War II and half of Donald Trump’s 4 percent goal.

Some of the slowdown reflects baby boomers’ retirement; the labor force isn’t shrinking but is expanding more slowly than in earlier years. To offset this drag, we need higher productivi­ty — more efficienci­es and valuable products — to raise output. Instead, productivi­ty growth has collapsed.

Based on data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, here are the average annual productivi­ty gains for four periods since 1950 — from 1950-70: 2.6 percent; 1970-90: 1.5 percent; 1990-2010: 1.9 percent; 2010-15: 0.4 percent.

As you can see, productivi­ty gains since 2010 have virtually disappeare­d. At this rate, incomes would double every 180 years. By contrast, they’d double in 36 years if annual productivi­ty increases averaged 2 percent.

Economists intensely debate what has caused this productivi­ty eclipse. Robert Gordon of Northweste­rn University argues that major technologi­cal breakthrou­ghs lie behind us. Others have cited too much government regulation, the hangover from the Great Recession (making companies and consumers more cautious), or mismeasure­ment (meaning that the true value of the internet is understate­d).

By scouring economic statistics, Greenspan thinks he’s discovered heretofore hidden relationsh­ips that explain weak productivi­ty growth.

What’s happening, he said recently at the conservati­ve American Enterprise Institute, is that spending on “entitlemen­ts” (Social Security, Medicare, food stamps and the like) is crowding out gross national saving. Since 1965, saving has dropped from 25 percent of the economy (gross domestic product) to about 18 percent of GDP. Meanwhile, entitlemen­t costs went from 5 percent of GDP to 15 percent.

“Entitlemen­ts” are what others call the welfare state. If we save less, we’re likely to invest less — so goes the argument — because

domestic savings are the largest source of funds for business capital spending. Less investment then reduces productivi­ty growth, because new investment­s typically embody the most efficient technologi­es.

That’s the Greenspan thesis in a nutshell: Entitlemen­ts are draining funds from productivi­ty-enhancing investment­s.

To be sure, there are caveats. Greenspan concedes that foreign investment in the United States offsets some of the drop in U.S. savings. But he thinks this is waning. What also depresses investment, he argues, is a lack of confidence in the future — pessimism he blames on costly government regulation­s (he mentions Dodd-Frank) and large unknowns (say, global warming).

So twin pressures curb new investment: higher interest rates caused by borrowing to pay for entitlemen­ts; and cautious companies who exhibit “a remarkably weak interest in investing in the longer run.” They’ll invest in new software but not in long-lasting projects. Think factories, hospitals and hotels.

Even Greenspan notes that his theory is politicall­y and intellectu­ally challenged. No one — including, it seems, President-elect Trump — wants to cut entitlemen­ts. Moreover, the long stretch of low interest rates makes it hard for most people to believe investment has been crowded out, he says. (For policy wonks, Greenspan contends that the higher rates show up as an increased “spread” between rates on five-year Treasury notes and 30year bonds.)

What other economists will think remains to be seen. An obvious question is whether Greenspan’s relationsh­ips are correlatio­ns, not cause and effect.

Still, there is at least one bit of good news. The forces that move productivi­ty are so complicate­d — not just investment, but manager and worker skills, research and developmen­t, competitiv­e markets and much more — that economists have consistent­ly failed to predict major turns, up or down. The next surprise could be an upturn.

If not, the implicatio­ns are sobering. As Greenspan put it: “What we are dealing with … is a huge problem which, as far as I can see, is almost insurmount­able.” It’s hard to disagree. Robert Samuelson writes a Washington Post column on economics.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States