Las Vegas Review-Journal

PRODUCTIVI­TY KEY TO COVERING COSTS AS UNEMPLOYME­NT RATE DECREASES

-

Recession, however — and, to a lesser extent, even during the stronger economic times that preceded it — productivi­ty growth has been confoundin­gly weak, forcing business owners and workers to compete over a relatively meager sliver of economic growth. There have been peaks and valleys, but not since the dot-com boom of the late 1990s and early 2000s has the U.S. economy consistent­ly delivered productivi­ty growth above 2 percent per year.

Now, some economists think a rebound could be on the way. For most of the recovery, wage growth has been anemic, suggesting companies faced relatively little pressure to invest in automation or to find other ways to squeeze more production out of workers. But as the labor market tightens, companies’ incentives could be changing.

“You could meet demand for a while by hiring workers, but with the unemployme­nt rate at 3.8 percent, eventually you’re going to run out of easy-to-find workers,” said John Fernald, an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and an expert on productivi­ty. “Because workers have other opportunit­ies, you end up having to pay them. And once you see wages going up, you say, ‘We have to become more productive to cover our costs.’ ”

That cycle could be underway. Wage growth has crept up over the past two years. One measure preferred by many economists, the Employment Cost Index, posted its strongest year-overyear growth since the recession in the first three months of the year. And there are other indication­s that companies are struggling to find workers. Applicatio­ns for disability insurance, for example, have begun to fall, a sign that companies may be more willing to look outside the standard labor pool to find employees. And while productivi­ty has yet to rebound, corporate investment — historical­ly a prelude to productivi­ty growth — has been rising.

David Maletto, who runs a small packaging company in Eau Claire, Wis., said it had become increasing­ly difficult to find workers with the local unemployme­nt rate below 3 percent. The company, which specialize­s in putting together variety packs of beers for Miller and other brewers, has had a particular­ly hard time holding on to unskilled laborers, who pack bottles into boxes and load them onto pallets. Turnover at those positions is constant, Maletto said, and the workers he finds to fill vacancies are often unreliable, showing up late, playing on their phones while on the clock or sometimes not showing up at all.

“We have customers continuall­y coming to us and they’re needing packaging done and we’ll have to say, ‘We can’t do that for you,’” Maletto said. “There were days when we might have to shut a line down.”

Maletto tried raising pay, first by 25 percent and then by an additional 20 percent. He now offers up to $12 an hour for unskilled jobs and has tried offering signing bonuses. But workers can earn as much as $5 an hour more elsewhere, a wage Maletto says he cannot afford, in part because multiyear contracts with some customers make it hard for him to raise prices.

So Maletto is turning to automation. Late last year, he installed a machine that loads filled boxes onto pallets; more sophistica­ted robots from APT, Nighswande­r’s firm, are set to arrive in August. Maletto took out a $1 million loan to pay for the equipment, a big gamble for a family-owned company. But with the labor pool shrinking, he said he had little doubt it was the right decision.

“If we don’t get things automated and we don’t start moving things forward, we’re going to be the ones who get left behind,” Maletto said.

Decisions like Maletto’s are not the way economists have historical­ly thought about productivi­ty growth. In traditiona­l economic models, productivi­ty is determined by technologi­cal advances and business innovation­s that are not tied to the ebb and flow of recessions and recoveries. The economic boom of the 1920s, according to the standard narrative, was enabled in part by the spread of electric power. A similar pattern played out in the 1990s with the rise of personal computers. In both cases, technology paved the way for productivi­ty, which in turn led to higher pay and faster growth.

But in recent years, some economists have begun to wonder if the convention­al models might get the relationsh­ip backward. Perhaps periods of strong economic growth are what put pressure on companies to innovate, or at least to figure out how to use new technologi­es to make themselves more efficient. Maybe it is not a coincidenc­e, in other words, that the last period of strong productivi­ty growth also coincided with the last time the unemployme­nt rate fell below 4 percent.

Gavin Wright, an economic historian at Stanford University who has studied the 1990s, argued that advances in informatio­n technology predated that productivi­ty surge by a decade or more. What changed in the 1990s, he said, is that the labor market tightened.

“Right around the middle of that decade, you did start to get rising real wages for the first time in quite a long time,” Wright said. “Employers will be driven to, or be more likely to, think about ways to economize if the labor’s more expensive.”

If Wright is correct, it could have significan­t implicatio­ns for economic policy. If productivi­ty growth is essentiall­y fixed in the short term, as traditiona­l models assume, then rising wages will most likely lead to faster inflation, as companies pass on higher costs to customers. That would likely force the Federal Reserve to raise interest rates more aggressive­ly to prevent the economy from overheatin­g.

But if companies instead respond to the tight labor market by taking steps to increase productivi­ty, then wages could rise without causing inflation. Under that approach, raising rates too quickly could be a costly mistake for the Fed, snuffing out the recovery before companies can make productivi­ty-enhancing investment­s. That would be a particular­ly costly mistake because those investment­s carry long-term benefits — robots installed during a boom can keep running even when the economy slows.

“The cost of running policy too tight is not just what we don’t produce this year, it’s all the lost production and lost income for many years ahead,” said J.W. Mason, an economist for the Roosevelt Institute, a left-leaning think tank.

Not all economists are convinced that the tight labor market will lead to a productivi­ty surge. Fernald, the San Francisco Fed economist, said the low unemployme­nt rate should stimulate investment, but a more meaningful accelerati­on in productivi­ty growth would require innovation. Jerome Powell, the Fed chairman, in a speech this month discussed the possibilit­y that the strong economy could spur productivi­ty growth but called the evidence for such an idea “sparse and inconclusi­ve.”

For now, the Fed appears to be sticking with the standard approach of gradually raising rates to ward off inflation. But the United States may be about to run an experiment on the effects of a high-pressure economy whether Powell wants to or not. The combinatio­n of tax cuts and government spending increases is adding fuel to an economy already burning hot. The Fed’s most recent projection­s estimate that the unemployme­nt rate will fall to 3.5 percent next year.

If that happens, the beneficiar­ies could be people like Mike Steffel. Steffel, 39, grew up near here and never went to college, instead finding work in various low-paying factory jobs. In one position at a local manufactur­er, he found himself drawn to the work done by skilled toolmakers.

“I saw what the journeymen were doing there and I thought that was something that I’d like to be doing as a career,” Steffel said. “You have this raw stock of steel that’s just sitting there, and making it into something useful, I like the thought of that.”

Eventually, Steffel saw an ad from APT saying it was hiring and would pay for classes at the local community college. Steffel works at APT as an apprentice during the two-year certificat­e program, and is committed to staying a year after it ends. In return, he gets training as a toolmaker, a skill that could ultimately earn him more than $70,000 a year with overtime. And the skills he is gaining are less easily replaced by robots.

“This is the career that I have chosen,” Steffel said. “I’m not going to get rich off it, but hopefully in the end, I’ll do well.”

For Nighswande­r, training people like Steffel is an investment. For years, he said, he complained that the people graduating from local high schools and colleges did not have the skills needed. But eventually he realized that he had to tackle the problem himself.

In 2015, APT opened a training center inside its 75,000-square-foot headquarte­rs. Every afternoon during the school year, eight to 10 students from the local high school spend two hours taking hands-on classes in electrical engineerin­g, machining, practical math and other subjects. The students earn school credit, and many also work at APT after hours.

Nighswande­r acknowledg­ed that many trainees would never work at APT after graduation. Some may even work for his competitor­s. But when skilled labor is scarce, he said, companies have to start taking matters into their own hands.

“There’s a whole bunch of gearheads out there, and there always have been, and they’re smart,” Nighswande­r said. “If manufactur­ers are not willing to invest in education, then the only thing they can do is steal an employee from another employer.”

 ?? PHOTOS BY ANDREW SPEAR / THE NEW YORK TIMES ?? Austin Henderson, left, a high school student, learns how to program robots May 10 at APT Manufactur­ing Solutions in Hicksville, Ohio. The pool of skilled workers is shallow in the area near the Ohio-indiana border where APT is based. The company has...
PHOTOS BY ANDREW SPEAR / THE NEW YORK TIMES Austin Henderson, left, a high school student, learns how to program robots May 10 at APT Manufactur­ing Solutions in Hicksville, Ohio. The pool of skilled workers is shallow in the area near the Ohio-indiana border where APT is based. The company has...
 ??  ?? Kyle Castillo programs a robot at APT Manufactur­ing Solutions
Kyle Castillo programs a robot at APT Manufactur­ing Solutions
 ??  ?? Employees work on the production floor at APT Manufactur­ing Solutions.
Employees work on the production floor at APT Manufactur­ing Solutions.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States