Marin Independent Journal

Requiring corporatio­ns to share emissions could backfire

- By Wayne Winegarden Wayne Winegarden is a senior fellow in business and economics at the Pacific Research Institute. Distribute­d by CalMatters.org.

In January, state Sen. Scott Wiener reintroduc­ed legislatio­n that would require companies with revenues exceeding $1 billion to disclose their greenhouse gas emissions. The San Francisco Democrat frames his proposal as a transparen­cy issue.

It's not, of course. If enacted, his proposal would worsen the state's business climate and increase costs on California­ns.

He says Senate Bill 253 is about “making sure our state and business community are putting our money where all of our mouths are, which is in a direction of climate action.”

At first glance, this logic appears reasonable. Global climate change is a problem and greater transparen­cy seems to provide important benefits. It helps investors better understand any potential litigation risks and customers better understand the impact on emissions from their consumptio­n choices.

Dig deeper, and it becomes clear that the legislatio­n does not promote the transparen­cy Wiener and the bill's supporters seek. Including the financial costs, this proposal would be a net negative for California­ns.

If enacted, companies must provide detailed carbon accounting reports that include emissions from their direct operations, their electricit­y purchased and the emissions generated by the company's supply chain and indirect activities.

Unlike financial reports that are based on a rigorous and widely accepted methodolog­y, carbon accounting reports are neither precise nor accurate.

The further away from a company's direct operations, the more inaccurate the carbon accounting exercise becomes. How does a company know which power generator provided the electricit­y they used? More troubling, how can they possibly know the emissions of distant suppliers?

They can't. Consequent­ly, companies will rely on proxy informatio­n that is just as likely to provide misinforma­tion as informatio­n. Comparing the emissions across companies will also be problemati­c. Difference­s could be due to actual emissions, but could also result from measuremen­t assumption­s.

Then there are the problems of double counting emission reductions, where multiple organizati­ons take credit for the same emissions reduction, which is another inherent problem of carbon accounting.

While the reports will provide informatio­n of dubious value, conducting the carbon accounting audits will be costly. Complying with the legislatio­n will require companies to devote additional financial resources, which will add to their costs. Like any cost increase, California consumers will bear these costs, in whole or part. Therefore, the mandates will add to the affordabil­ity problems that too many California families are already struggling to overcome.

The costs from the proposal will increase over time because fundamenta­l business considerat­ions such as choosing the supplier that produces the right inputs, at the right price, that meet the necessary delivery schedule, will receive less emphasis. By disincenti­vizing the creation of the most efficient supply chain possible, the mandate will have harmful impacts on corporate costs. Once again, these costs will be passed to consumers.

The mandate is also troubling because there are better policy options. The costs of global climate change can be addressed without making California's families poorer if policies focus on incentiviz­ing the necessary technologi­cal innovation­s rather than imposing higher costs on families already struggling to make ends meet.

There are many exciting innovation­s in developmen­t that include next generation nuclear plants, enhanced battery storage, carbon capture and storage processes, technologi­es that significan­tly improve fuel efficiency, and the developmen­t of hydrogen and alternativ­e power sources.

Whether any, or several, of these technologi­es will ultimately pan out is unknown. Continued investment into these (and other lesser-known innovation­s) is necessary to encourage the emergence of the nextgenera­tion energy sources. Policies that focus on reducing the cost of innovation through tax and depreciati­on preference­s are better positioned to harness the private sector's innovation to cost-effectivel­y reduce emissions.

A policy that provides no benefits but increases costs on families and businesses imposes net costs on California­ns.

In the last legislativ­e session, the Assembly justifiabl­y rejected the prior version of the bill. For the sake of California's families, let's hope they do so again this year.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States