Milwaukee Journal Sentinel

Fed has little room to maneuver rates

Going negative is too much risk of deflation or sharp inflation

- TOM SALER Tom Saler is an author and freelance financial journalist in Madison. He can be reached at tomsaler.com.

For most of the last 30 years, U.S. inflation has resided in a kind of sweet spot for investors and the economy — low enough to keep interest rates down and asset prices up, but not so low as to risk ruinous deflation.

That remarkable period of stability seems set to end. Among the many consequenc­es of the coronaviru­s recession is its likely impact on consumer prices, first down and then up.

Since the Great Recession ended in 2009, policymake­rs at the Federal Reserve have worried that inflation would be too low when the next recession struck, a risk akin to an airplane encounteri­ng turbulence while barely airborne.

Those fears have been realized. With interest rates already at low levels when the recession began, the Fed has little room to maneuver rates lower without taking them into negative territory, a place where policymake­rs prefer not to go.

Potentiall­y, too low inflation could trigger structural deflation — chronicall­y falling prices across much of the U.S. economy — in the same self-perpetuati­ng spiral that has kept Japan in a perpetual state of slow growth and intermitte­nt recession since the early 1990s.

Over the near term, the economic effects of the COVID-19 pandemic in the U.S. will be strongly deflationary. Headline inflation could soon drop below zero given weak energy prices and fewer places for consumers to spend. But even core inflation, which excludes food and energy, could turn negative, at least until the economy begins to bounce off the bottom this summer.

What if rates go negative?

The Fed has a stated goal for inflation of 2%, as measured by its preferred metric, the core personal consumptio­n expenditur­es index. That index peaked at 10% in the mid-1970s and the early 1980s, before starting a long and gradual decline, a healthy process known as disinflation.

Core PCE has failed to meet the Fed’s 2% target in all but 14 of the 138 months since the peak of the financial crisis in late 2008, despite unusually low interest rates.

Though Fed chair Jerome Powell insists that the central bank has plenty of monetary ammunition remaining, even after using $2.3 trillion in an initial round of emergency lending, the possibilit­y exists that benchmark rates eventually will drop below zero, as they already have in Europe and Japan.

Negative interest rates are what they seem: depositors effectively pay financial institutio­ns to hold their money, a penalty intended to induce savers to spend, businesses to borrow, and banks to lend.

But deflation isn’t the only risk. Paradoxica­lly, there are also concerns of an abrupt rise in inflation, perhaps even to 1970s levels, when consumers feel safe enough to resume their normal lives. In the context of what is likely to remain a sluggish economy for years to come, expectatio­ns for slow growth and high inflation — dubbed stagflation in earlier times — could become a self-reinforcin­g prophecy. Near term, deflation is the far greater risk. Unambiguou­s Fed backing for government and corporate bonds should keep the fixed-income market a relatively stable, if not particular­ly lucrative, place to park funds.

Perhaps as early as mid-2021, however, consumer prices could spike as trillions of government created and dispensed dollars chase a pool of goods and services shrunken by bankruptci­es, broken supply chains and idled factories. Though central banks have grown their balance sheets by trillions of dollars over the last decade without an inflationary effect, that earlier digital money was easily absorbed by a global savings glut and underfunde­d pension funds.

Government­s also will be incentiviz­ed to inflate their way out of debt, as did Germany after World War I and the U.S. after World War II. America alone could add at least $3 trillion to a national debt that already was slightly above 100% of GDP even before the pandemic recession.

The economic historian Robert Skidelsky recently cautioned that the world economy could suffer an “inflationary depression” as rising consumer prices interact with high unemployme­nt.

For three decades, low and stable goods and services inflation underwrote asset inflation by removing the threat of tighter monetary policy, and by making cash unattracti­ve.

In one way or another, that Golden Age of consumer price stability seems likely to end, yet another casualty of the worst public health crisis in 100 years.

Since the Great Recession ended in 2009, policymake­rs at the Federal Reserve have worried inflation would be too low when the next recession struck, a risk akin to an airplane encounteri­ng turbulence while barely airborne. Those fears have been realized.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States