Pittsburgh Post-Gazette

Winners and losers

Compensati­on is no longer a practical response to globalizat­ion’s adverse effects, argues economist DANI RODRIK

- Dani Rodrik, the Ford Foundation Professor of Internatio­nal Political Economy at Harvard Kennedy School, is a columnist for Project Syndicate.

It appears that a new consensus has taken hold these days among the world’s business and policy elites about how to address the antiglobal­ization backlash that populists such as Donald Trump have so ably exploited. Gone are the confident assertions that globalizat­ion benefits everyone: We must, the elites now concede, accept that globalizat­ion produces both winners and losers. But the correct response is not to halt or reverse globalizat­ion; it is to ensure that the losers are compensate­d.

The new consensus is stated succinctly by Nouriel Roubini: The backlash against globalizat­ion “can be contained and managed through policies that compensate workers for its collateral damage and costs,” he argues. “Only by enacting such policies will globalizat­ion’s losers begin to think that they may eventually join the ranks of its winners.”

This argument seems to make eminent sense, both economical­ly and politicall­y. Economists have long known that trade liberaliza­tion causes income redistribu­tion and absolute losses for some groups, even as it enlarges a country’s overall economic pie. Therefore, trade deals unambiguou­sly enhance national wellbeing only to the extent that winners compensate losers. Compensati­on also ensures support for trade openness from broader constituen­cies and should be good politics.

Prior to the welfare state, the tension between openness and redistribu­tion was resolved either by large-scale emigration of workers or by re-imposing trade protection, especially in agricultur­e. With the rise of the welfare state, the constraint became less binding, allowing for more trade liberaliza­tion. Today the advanced countries that are the most exposed to the internatio­nal economy are also those where safety nets and social insurance programs — welfare states — are the most extensive. Research in Europe has shown that losers from globalizat­ion within countries tend to favor more active social programs and labor-market interventi­ons.

If opposition to trade has not become politicall­y salient in Europe today, it is partly because such social protection­s remain strong there, despite having weakened in recent years. It is not an exaggerati­on to say that the welfare state and the open economy have been flip sides of

the same coin during much of the 20th century.

Compared to most European countries, the United States was a latecomer to globalizat­ion. Until recently, its large domestic market and relative geographic­al insulation provided considerab­le protection from imports, especially from lowwage countries. It also traditiona­lly had a weak welfare state.

When the United States began opening itself up to imports from Mexico, China and other developing countries in the 1980s, one might have expected it to go the European route. Instead, under the sway of Reaganite and market-fundamenta­list ideas, the U.S. went in an opposite direction. As Larry Mishel, president of the Economic Policy Institute, puts it, “ignoring the losers was deliberate.” In 1981, the “trade adjustment assistance program was one of the first things Reagan attacked, cutting its weekly compensati­on payments.”

The damage continued under subsequent, Democratic administra­tions. In Mr. Mishel’s words, “if freetrader­s had actually cared about the working class, they could have supported a full range of policies to support robust wage growth: full employment, collective bargaining, high labor standards, a robust minimum wage, and so on.” And all of this could have been done “before administer­ing ‘shocks’ by expanding trade with low-wage countries.”

Could the U.S. now reverse course, and follow the newly emergent convention­al wisdom? Back in 2007, political scientist Ken Scheve and economist Matt Slaughter called for “a New Deal for globalizat­ion” in the U.S., one that would link “engagement with the world economy to a substantia­l redistribu­tion of income.” In the U.S., they argued, this would mean adopting a much more progressiv­e federal tax system.

Mr. Slaughter had served in a Republican administra­tion, under President George W. Bush. It is an indication of how polarized the U.S. political climate has become that it is impossible to imagine similar proposals coming out of Republican circles these days. The effort by Mr. Trump and his Congressio­nal allies to emasculate President Barack Obama’s signature healthinsu­rance program reflected Republican­s’ commitment to scaling back, not expanding, social protection­s.

Today’s consensus concerning the need to compensate globalizat­ion’s losers presumes that the winners are motivated by enlightene­d self-interest — that they believe buy-in from the losers is essential to maintain economic openness. Mr. Trump’s presidency has revealed an alternativ­e perspectiv­e: Globalizat­ion, at least as currently construed, tilts the balance of political power toward those with the skills and assets to benefit from openness, underminin­g whatever organized influence the losers might have had in the first place. Inchoate discontent about globalizat­ion, Mr. Trump has shown, can easily be channeled to serve an altogether different agenda, more in line with elites’ interests.

The politics of compensati­on is always subject to a problem that economists call “time inconsiste­ncy.” Before a new policy — say, a trade agreement — is adopted, beneficiar­ies have an incentive to promise compensati­on. Once the policy is in place, they have little interest in following through, either because reversal is costly all around or because the underlying balance of power shifts toward them.

The time for compensati­on has come and gone. Even if compensati­on was a viable approach two decades ago, it no longer serves as a practical response to globalizat­ion’s adverse effects. To bring the losers along, we will need to consider changing the rules of globalizat­ion itself.

 ?? Daniel Marsula/Post-Gazette ??
Daniel Marsula/Post-Gazette

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States