Pittsburgh Post-Gazette

Birth of an oligarchy

-

Mr. Cost indicates that Hamilton designed his financial plan (which advocated immediate assumption of state debt, a central bank to create a uniform national currency and extend credit, and subsidies to manufactur­ers) to align the interests of the wealthy few to the priorities of the United States government. In his indifferen­ce to conflicts of interest among public officials “and the greed and small-mindedness of the speculativ­e class, which attached itself like a barnacle to his administra­tion,” Mr. Cost writes, Hamilton exhibited “shocking naiveté.”

Mr. Cost attributes Madison’s subsequent support for a central bank, protective tariffs and federal spending on internal improvemen­ts to the reduced relevance of “agrarian republican­ism,” the growth of manufactur­ing and commerce, an ideologica­lly adrift political party desperatel­y in need of a new direction,” and a conviction that the benefits of his policies would be more broadly distribute­d throughout the country. His approach, Mr. Cost suggests, not all that convincing­ly, was less a capitulati­on than “a synthesis of Hamilton vigor and Madisonian balance.”

At the same time, however, Mr. Cost insists that Madison and his Democratic-Republican colleagues “were wrong to set aside their own worries about corruption.” Their “scheme,” he adds, “tended to exacerbate rather than mitigate the threat.”

Mr. Cost’s thesis, it turns out, is that the Madison of 1787 was fundamenta­lly right, after all. The Madisonian-Hamiltonia­n “hybrid,” the author declares, produced a Second Bank of the United States that “fomented oligarchy” and a “Tariff of Abominatio­ns” that “facilitate­d an ochlocracy, or mob rule,” consisting of a majority faction that enriched its members, harmed the South “and did nothing for the national interest.”

The realities of antebellum America, in my judgment, do not support Mr. Cost’s characteri­zations of government policies. The “oligarchy” folded in the wake of President Andrew Jackson’s veto of the bill renewing the charter of the bank he called a “monster.” And, although Mr. Cost claims that the geographic­al expansion of the United States “could not prevent majority factions” from abusing the fundamenta­l principles of “the great desideratu­m,” he acknowledg­es that Henry Clay and John C. Calhoun engineered a compromise that reduced rates, which remained “reasonable” for decades. The mob, apparently, had no staying power.

Virtually no one, in my mind, disagrees with the age-old claim that nations with substantia­l commercial and manufactur­ing sectors, growing population­s and aspiration­s to global power are more prone to corruption than those dominated by yeoman farmers. Or with the propositio­n that some people (usually elites) benefit more than others fromgovern­ment policies.

Madisonian factions (encapsulat­ed these days in the phenomenon called pluralism) and organizati­ons of the previously unorganize­d, have, to some degree, mitigated these tendencies. That said, corruption and inequality have been and continue to be pervasive in American society.

“The Price of Greatness” concludes with a plea to Americans to “remember that sovereignt­y belongs to the people” and “demand a return to republican propriety.” If they do, Mr. Cost predicts, “the government will acquiesce.”

Along with many other Americans, color me uncertain about the 21st century content of republican propriety, the role of government, the “proper” balance between republican­ism and nationalis­m, and the “price of greatness.”

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States