San Francisco Chronicle

Will we have productivi­ty boom next?

- By Neil Irwin Neil Irwin is a New York Times writer.

Two of the most important facts about the global economy over the past decade are these: A giant financial crisis led to mass unemployme­nt in many countries and years of disappoint­ing growth. And despite a seeming barrage of technologi­cal innovation, productivi­ty growth has been the weakest in decades.

Maybe it’s not a coincidenc­e.

That is the provocativ­e conclusion of new research from the McKinsey Global Institute, the inhouse think tank of the consulting giant, that suggests we should change how we think about the advancemen­ts that make society richer over time. It implies that as the economy returns to full employment, an outburst of faster growth in productivi­ty — and hence economic growth — is a real possibilit­y.

This idea should excite both conservati­ves and liberals.

It suggests that the Trump administra­tion’s ambitions for faster growth driven by rising productivi­ty aren’t as outlandish as warier forecaster­s have argued. And it tends to back arguments by liberal-leaning commentato­rs that the Federal Reserve ought to move cautiously in raising interest rates, in hope that the economy will more fully repair itself from damage caused by the 2008 recession and its aftermath.

For years, McKinsey researcher­s have tried to understand what drives productivi­ty growth. They’ve studied how innovation­s that enable a company to make more goods and services per hour of labor spread across the economy.

The latest wrinkle is that the researcher­s now believe that productivi­ty growth depends not just on the supply side of the economy — what companies produce and what technologi­es they use to do it — but also significan­tly on the demand side. That is to say, productivi­ty advancemen­ts don’t happen in a vacuum just because technology is available.

They also happen because companies need to increase production to match demand for their goods, and a shortage, either of workers or of materials, forces them to think creatively about how to do so.

“We have always looked at this from the supply side to a large extent,” said James Manyika, a partner at the firm and a co-author of the study. “You look at companies and the introducti­on of technology and business processes, the adoption of best practices. We’ve always kind of assumed away the demand side of the equation.”

From the mid-1980s through 2008, that seemed like a reasonable approach. Recessions then, sometimes called the Great Moderation, tended to be short and mild. But the deeper and more prolonged downturn that affected the United States and Europe since has made at least some economists rethink their assumption­s.

U.S. productivi­ty growth was 3.8 percentage points lower in the period from 2010 to 2014 compared with the 20002004 period. Part of that, McKinsey found, was a result of the informatio­n technology boom of the 1990s — which paid continuing productivi­ty dividends into the first years of the 21st century — having run its course. But 1.1 percentage points of the drop was due, in its analysis, to aftereffec­ts of the financial crisis. Those effects sapped even more productivi­ty growth, 1.3 percentage points, from the British economy.

Take the auto industry. U.S. production fell 50 percent from 2007 to 2009, meaning the sector had tremendous excess production capacity in the ensuing years even as the sector recovered.

“Companies could fulfill a lot higher demand without having to make any new investment­s,” said Jaana Remes, a McKinsey partner and a co-author. “Typically, the newest technology is implemente­d in the latest factories. People don’t upgrade a factory that can fulfill demand perfectly well.”

Or consider how this dynamic might apply in the restaurant industry (or retail, or tourism).

The basic technology for self-serve kiosks has been around for years. But when the unemployme­nt rate was at its postcrisis highs, employers could have their pick of good workers at relatively low prices. Now, with the jobless rate at 4.1 percent, good workers are harder to find. And, perhaps unsurprisi­ngly, companies have been more open to installing technology that may have a significan­t up-front cost and require reworking how a restaurant is organized, but allow more sales without hiring more workers.

“A consequenc­e of a really tight labor market is a higher turnover rate,” said Liah Luther, marketing manager at Nextep Systems, a Michigan company that sells selforderi­ng kiosks to restaurant­s, casinos and corporate facilities. “Once you eliminate the need for extensive training on a point-of-sale system, you can focus on soft skills like customer service, and reduce the cost of turnover.”

The optimistic case for both productivi­ty and overall economic growth goes like this: For several years, a lack of demand and plenty of spare capacity of both workers and equipment has made businesses complacent and unwilling to invest in new equipment, software or new ways of doing things that might allow more output per hour of labor.

Now, with companies having a harder time finding qualified workers and with demand for their products rising, they’ll have no choice but to re-engineer how they work to try to increase productivi­ty. Higher productivi­ty will, in turn, make it easier to justify higher wages, creating a self-reinforcin­g cycle of higher economic growth.

There are some risks to that rosy forecast, which Remes and Manyika warn about.

They see a great deal of potential from digitizati­on of businesses that have been slow to embrace the lessons of the cuttingedg­e companies in their industry. But this might be slow to generate the kinds of big productivi­ty gains that are possible.

Even as more retailers adapt to an age of digital commerce and learn from Amazon, for example, they may in the near term end up simply doubling up traditiona­l retail and e-commerce-focused workers, making such companies less productive rather than more.

And if automation leads to more income going to owners of capital, who already tend be wealthy, that could hollow out middle-class jobs and fuel higher inequality.

“Unless displaced labor can find new highly productive and high-wage occupation­s, workers may end up in low-wage jobs that create a drag on productivi­ty growth,” the McKinsey researcher­s wrote.

 ?? Nicole Bengiveno / New York Times 2004 ?? Self-service kiosks might be used more often if companies have trouble finding employees.
Nicole Bengiveno / New York Times 2004 Self-service kiosks might be used more often if companies have trouble finding employees.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States