Santa Fe New Mexican

New rules designed to keep people out

- David Bier is an immigratio­n policy analyst at the Cato Institute. This was first published in the Washington Post.

President Donald Trump’s administra­tion rolled out its most significan­t change yet to immigratio­n policy Monday: the “public charge” rule. This regulation will ban legal immigrants if government bureaucrat­s believe they might use welfare. Officials claim the rule will protect taxpayers and make immigrants self-sufficient, but the rule isn’t designed to meet these goals. It’s just designed to keep immigrants out.

In the late 19th century, when Congress first passed the law on which the regulation relies, a “public charge” meant a ward of the state — someone who the government had the primary responsibi­lity to care for. These people lived in “almshouses” and were entirely dependent on the government for their subsistenc­e. Congress rightly decided it wanted only immigrants who could support themselves or be supported by family or private charity.

As almshouses disappeare­d and the modern welfare state emerged, implementa­tion of the public-charge standard fluctuated arbitraril­y depending on the administra­tion. Finally, in 1999, the Immigratio­n and Naturaliza­tion Service introduced a clear definition of a public charge: anyone who receives most of their cash income from the government. This standard accounted for both the receipt of benefits but also how much the immigrants were supporting themselves.

But the Trump administra­tion rejects this historic understand­ing. Its rule will ban immigrants if they might — again, in the future — use any welfare at all (including noncash programs such as Medicaid) for more than 12 months in any 36-month period. Using four different programs for three months would count as 12 months of use, making anyone who falls on hard times for even the briefest period a “public charge.”

The real problem with the new definition is not that it’s harsh; immigrants can certainly survive without welfare. The problem is that it’s economical­ly misguided. No one who cares about public finances would design a rule that entirely ignores the degree to which the immigrants support themselves. Mere use — projected by a bureaucrat in any amount — would trigger a public-charge denial, even if it was a tiny fraction of the person’s income.

The problem with the rule runs deeper. The entire methodolog­y of how a bureaucrat will predict someone’s

future likelihood to use benefits is designed to set immigrants up to fail. It sets up a checklist of factors, including age, education, family size, English language ability, income, assets, etc. The government plans to count the negative factors and “weigh” them against the positive ones.

But empiricall­y, it’s just not true that a person with two “negative” factors is twice as likely to use government benefits than someone with just one factor in isolation — or any more likely at all. For example, the government plans to “negatively weight” dropping out of high school and not speaking English. But someone who both dropped out of high school and doesn’t speak English is no likelier to use benefits than someone who just dropped out of high school.

This wouldn’t be a big deal if these factors in isolation were good predictors of welfare use. But according to data that the government cites in the rule, they aren’t. Nearly 70 percent of noncitizen­s who don’t speak English didn’t use any welfare at all in 2013. This was virtually the same percentage as for high school dropouts.

In other words, these factors aren’t good at predicting welfare use, and few immigrants — just 1 in 5, according to government data — used any welfare in 2013. Still, the government plans to use these factors anyway. Adding this inaccurate and misleading methodolog­y to an already hopelessly flawed definition will produce disaster for legal immigrants. When the rule takes effect in October, legal immigrants will receive a blitz of denials.

Barring noncitizen­s from welfare makes sense. But banning immigrants from the country based on an inaccurate methodolog­y won’t help public finances because most immigrants, according to the National Academy of Sciences, will pay more in taxes than they receive in benefits over their lives.

Far from helping to “protect taxpayers” and requiring self-sufficienc­y, the public-charge rule will harm the economy by turning away hardworkin­g immigrants who are contributi­ng to the United States. Unfortunat­ely, the effect of the misguided policy is — for the president — a feature, not a bug.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States