Texarkana Gazette

Why unions can’t help workers adapt to today’s economy

- James Sherk The heriTage FoundaTion

W and beyond their union rates. United Food and Commercial Workers Local 23 promptly filed suit. It wanted seniority alone to determine pay. The arbitrator sided with the union and ordered the performanc­e-raises rescinded. This mindset turns off many workers.

Alan Krueger, the former chair of President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisors, has found that almost all the decline in U.S. union membership is “due to a decline in worker demand for union representa­tion.”

Employees have a federally protected right to unionize. The fact that union membership keeps falling suggests the White House has misdiagnos­ed workers’ problems. A far greater challenge facing many workers is how to adapt to the ongoing transforma­tion of the economy.

For the past generation, employment has fallen in jobs that require routine skills and grown in non-routine jobs. Routine jobs tend to lie in the middle of the skill distributi­on; non-routine jobs at the hat is the largest challenge workers face today? President Barack Obama believes the answer is not enough union representa­tion. That’s why the White House recently hosted a summit arguing for expanding union membership.

But what unions have to offer now appeals to few workers. Focusing on them diverts attention from greater barriers in the workplace.

Of course management gets the union it deserves. Employees have a statutory right to unionize. Employees mistreated at work will probably exercise that right. But union representa­tion has fallen primarily because most workers see little value in it.

Unions have little ability to raise wages anymore. In today’s competitiv­e economy, unionized firms cannot pass on those costs as higher prices; their customers will go elsewhere. The average union member makes more than the average non-union member, but primarily because union organizers target higher-paying companies to begin with.

Economists have compared companies whose workers vote to unionize to those that vote not to. Pay grows just as fast at the companies that remained non-union.

But without higher pay, unions only offer workers general representa­tion. Many workers do not want these services. Collective union contracts necessaril­y ignore their individual contributi­ons.

Consider what happened when a Giant Eagle grocery store in Pennsylvan­ia tried to reward its employees’ hard work. Managers gave two dozen workers performanc­e-based raises above

top and bottom of it. The economy needs far fewer secretarie­s and assembly line workers than it once did. It also needs far more homecare aides and IT specialist­s.

MIT economist David Autor has found this “job polarizati­on” has occurred in every major EU country. It has happened in countries with strong unions and weak unions, with high taxes and low taxes. This strongly suggests that factors like globalizat­ion and technologi­cal advances—not union’s decline—drive this trend.

On the whole, these changes have raised living standards. But they have created serious challenges for many workers who formerly held routine jobs. Union membership can’t change this. A better response is to improve and expand access to education. This would better prepare workers for the new jobs the economy is creating.

Just as importantl­y, the government should remove barriers that prevent workers from taking jobs they could succeed in. One-third of jobs in the economy now require a government license to perform. Some of these requiremen­ts make sense; surgeons should have considerab­le training before operating on people. But many of these licenses involve jobs without safety concerns.

Louisiana licenses florists. Florida licenses interior designers. Maryland counties license fortune tellers. Every state licenses barbers—requiring an average of a year of training before they can cut hair. Does it really take a year of training to avoid bad haircuts?

In fact trade associatio­ns— not consumer groups—lobby for these restrictio­ns. Licensing keeps potential competitor­s out. That benefits incumbent practition­ers, at the cost of higher prices for consumers and reduced opportunit­ies for those changing jobs. It most hurts disadvanta­ged workers; they can least afford to stop working to jump through bureaucrat­ic hoops.

For example, Dallas police arrested Isis Brantley for braiding African-American women’s hair without a cosmetolog­y license. That license required 1,500 hours of training and had nothing to do with hair braiding. So the mother of five did not obtain it. For that she went to jail and lost her job.

Earlier this year the Texas legislatur­e eliminated that unnecessar­y requiremen­t. Brantley can now freely teach and practice hair braiding. But similar licensing requiremen­ts in other states and occupation­s wall off a third of the economy to job-switchers. Similarly, many states are attempting to regulate new-economy companies such as Uber and Airbnb out of existence.

Policymake­rs should allow more Americans to work without needing government permission. That would do far more than union membership to address their current challenges.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States